Location: Global

#AcademicsStandWithUkraine

20220301 Ukraine support

The Forum for Research on Eastern Europe and Emerging Economies (FREE Network) stands for peace, security and democracy and condemns Russia’s invasion of the independent and democratic nation of Ukraine and violation of international law.

The FREE Network has an extensive history of building networks and partnerships with leading academic experts on economic issues in Central and Eastern Europe and emerging markets.

The FREE Network invites academics from the region and beyond to express their solidarity with the Ukrainian people, academics, educators, and students suffering from Russia’s invasion into the democratic nation of Ukraine.

To speak out on Russia’s aggression against Ukraine, please use the hashtag #AcademicsStandWithUkraine.

Donations for humanitarian aid are organized by the Kyiv School of Economics, a member of the FREE Network.

20220227 KSE fund raising

Data Science for Justice: Evidence from a Randomized Judicial Reform in the Kenyan Judiciary

20220329 Data Science for Justice Image 01

Can data science be used to improve the functioning of courts, and unlock the positive effects of institutions on economic development? Join SITE Brown Bag Seminar with Daniel Chen, Professor at the Toulouse School of Economics, on 29 March 2022.

Data Science for Justice

In a nationwide randomized experiment in Kenyan courts, authors develop and implement an algorithm that uses data regularly captured by administrative systems, identifies for each court their main sources of delay, and provides court-specific actionable recommendations on how to increase performance. Authors find that this intervention reduces delays, especially when the information is also shared with court user committees that include representatives from civil society, lawyers, and police. Authors find downstream economic effects of court speed, especially on contract-intensive industries.

Daniel Chen, Professor at the Toulouse School of Economics

Daniel Li Chen is the Lead Principal Investigator, DE JURE (Data and Evidence for Justice Reform) at the World Bank, Director of Research at the Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique (CNRS), and Professor at the Toulouse School of Economics (TSE). He is also a Senior Fellow at the Institute for Advanced Study in Toulouse, Collaborator at Harvard Medical School, advisor at NYU Courant Institute for Mathematics Center for Data Science.

He is the founder of oTree Open Source Research Foundation and Data Science Justice Collaboratory and co-founder of Justice Innovation Lab. Chen was previously Chair of Law and Economics at ETH and tenure-track assistant professor in Law (primary), Economics, and Public Policy at Duke University.

Daniel Li Chen received his BA and MS from Harvard University in Applied Mathematics and Economics; Economics PhD from MIT; and JD from Harvard Law School. He has attained prominence through the development of open source tools to study human behavior and through large-scale empirical studies — data science, artificial intelligence, and machine learning — on the relationship between law, social norms and the enforcement of legal norms, and on judicial systems.

Register for the Seminar

The link to the seminar will be distributed by invitation only. If you are interested to attend the seminar – please contact site@hhs.se. Follow the instructions below: Type the subject box with “Brown bag seminar *INSERT SEMINAR TITLE*” Indicate your affiliation and field of interest. For registered applicants, a Zoom link will be provided prior to the event via email with further instructions.

Disclaimer: Opinions expressed during events, seminars and conferences are those of the authors; they do not necessarily reflect those of the FREE Network and its research institutes.

Russian Oil and Gas: What to Expect?

20220524 The Energy and Climate Crisis Image 02

For decades Russian oil and gas have been an essential part of European energy imports. But due to the Russian invasion of Ukraine, oil and gas toward the west will be sharply curtailed or even stopped, by an initiative of either party.

How oil and gas flow reduction can affect global energy markets? And how big a problem is it for the EU and Russia?

Experts discussed what the Russian oil and gas flow reduction means for global markets

  • Julius Andersson, Assistant Professor at the Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics (SITE)
  • Chloé Le Coq, Professor at the Université Paris 2 Panthéon-Assas and Research Fellow at SITE,
  • Sergej Gubin, Research Fellow at BICEPS, and
  • Paweł Wróbel, Managing Director of the BalticWind.EU

Disclaimer: Opinions expressed during events, seminars and conferences are those of the authors; they do not necessarily reflect those of the FREE Network and its research institutes.

Fleeing the War Zone: Will Open Hearts be Enough?

20220311 Temporary image

The invasion of the Russian Federation in Ukraine has resulted in the loss of lives and destruction of infrastructure and has forced millions to flee from the war zone.

By March 14th 2022 over 2,8 million people have found refuge outside of Ukraine and many more have been displaced within its borders. The UNHCR estimates the total number of those forced to flee Ukraine may grow to 4 million.

Program

On March 14, 2022 experts from Ukraine, Sweden and Poland discussed the consequences of the invasion for the Ukrainian population.

Disclaimer: Opinions expressed during events, seminars and conferences are those of the authors; they do not necessarily reflect those of the FREE Network and its research institutes.

Fleeing the War Zone: Will Open Hearts be Enough?

20220311 Temporary image

The invasion of the Russian Federation in Ukraine has resulted in the loss of lives and destruction of infrastructure and has forced millions to flee from the war zone. 

Program

By March 9th 2022 over 2,1 million people have found refuge outside of Ukraine and many more have been displaced within its borders. The UNHCR estimates the total number of those forced to flee Ukraine may grow to 4 million. 

Join the webinar on March 14 to discuss the consequences of the invasion for the Ukrainian population with:

Registration

The webinar will be available to join via the Zoom platform. However, registration is required. Please register via Zoom (click here). After registration, you will receive a confirmation email which includes the Zoom link and passcode.

Disclaimer: Opinions expressed during events, seminars and conferences are those of the authors; they do not necessarily reflect those of the FREE Network and its research institutes.

Russian Oil and Gas: What to Expect?

20220310 Russian Oil and Gas

For decades Russian oil and gas have been an essential part of European energy imports. Now, two weeks into the fighting in Ukraine, there is an increasing concern that the flows of Russian oil and gas toward the west will be sharply curtailed, or even stopped, by an initiative of either party.


Program

This Thursday on March 10, Julius Andersson, Assistant Professor at the Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics (SITE), together with Chloé Le Coq, Professor at the Université Paris 2 Panthéon-Assas and Research Fellow at SITE, Sergej Gubin, Research Fellow at BICEPS, and Paweł Wróbel, Managing Director of the BalticWind.EU will discuss what the Russian oil and gas flow reduction means for global markets.

What are the likely implications of the Russian oil and gas ban for the EU? How oil and gas flow reduction can affect global energy markets? How big a problem is it for Russia? Join the webinar and learn more.

Registration

The webinar will be available to join via the Zoom platform. However, registration is required. Please register via the Zoom registration platform (click here). After registration, you will receive a confirmation email which includes the Zoom link and passcode.

Disclaimer: Opinions expressed during events, seminars and conferences are those of the authors; they do not necessarily reflect those of the FREE Network and its research institutes.

The Sanctions on Russia, and Their Impact on the Region

20220303 The Sanctions on Russia Image

As fighting across Ukraine escalates and the international community reacts, Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics (SITE) and the FREE Network invite you to join the webinar “The sanctions on Russia, and their impact on the region” on 3 March, 17:00 – 18:00 CET Stockholm.

The Sanctions on Russia, and Their Impact on the Region

Torbjörn Becker, Director of SITE will be joined by Larry Samuelson, Professor at Yale and Cowles Foundation, Lev Lvovsky, BEROC Research Fellow, Nataliia Shapoval, Chairman of KSE Institute and Yaroslava V. Babych, Academic Director of ISET Policy Institute and other experts with extensive policy experience for a live discussion about the economic effects of sanctions in Russia and the region.

Registration

Everyone is invited to join the webinar. Please use the Zoom registration platform to register (click here). After registration, you will receive a confirmation email which includes the Zoom link and passcode. Please also check the spam folder, not to miss the registration access details.

Disclaimer: Opinions expressed during events, seminars and conferences are those of the authors; they do not necessarily reflect those of the FREE Network and its research institutes.

Investing, Producing and Paying Taxes Under Weak Property Rights

20220124 Gas Crisis European Energy Image 05

Oil majors often choose to operate in countries with weak property rights. This may appear surprising, since the lack of constraints on governments may create incentives to renege on initial promises with firms and renegotiate tax payments once investments have occurred and, in the worst case, expropriate the firm. In theory, backloading investments, production and tax payments may be used to create self-enforcing agreements which do not depend on legal enforcement. Using a new dataset covering the universe of oil majors’ assets that started production between 1974 and 1999, we indeed show in a recent CEPR Working Paper (Paltseva, Toews, and Troya-Martinez, 2022) that investments, production and tax payments are delayed by two years in countries with weak institutions relative to countries with strong institutions. Extending the dataset back to 1960 and exploiting the transition to a new world oil order where expropriation became easier, allows us to interpret our estimates as causal. In particular, prior to the transition expropriations were not feasible, due to the omnipresent and credible military threat imposed by the oil majors’ countries of origin. As the new order sat in, a new equilibrium emerged, in which expropriations became a feasible option. This transition incited an increase in expropriations and forced firms to adjust to the new reality by backloading contracts.

The Hold-up Problem

In December of 2006, when the oil price was climbing towards new heights, the Guardian reported that the Russian government was about to successfully force Shell into transferring their controlling stake in a huge liquified gas project back into the hands of the government. While officially this was motivated by environmental concerns surrounding the Sakhalin-II project, most observers agreed that this might be considered a textbook example of the hold-up problem faced by oil firms when investing in countries with limited constraints on the executive. At its core, the hold-up problem refers to the idea that the government may renege on the initial promise and appropriate a bigger share of the pie once investments have been made. Obviously, this is not an oil-specific issue and concerns any type of investment in countries with weak property rights. Academics, who worked on resolving these issues, suggest the use of self-enforcing agreements (Thomas and Worrall, 1994). These agreements use future gains from trade (as opposed to third-party enforcement) to incentivize the governments not to expropriate. And while the theoretical literature has prolifically developed over the last 30 years (Ray, 2002), to the best of our knowledge no empirical evidence has been provided on the use and dynamic patterns of self-enforcing backloaded contracts.

Data and Sample

In Paltseva, Toews and Troya-Martinez (2022), we rely on micro-level data on oil and gas projects provided by Rystad Energy, an energy consultancy based in Norway. Its database contains current and historical data on physical, geological and financial features for the universe of oil and gas assets. We focus on the assets owned by the oil majors (BP, Chevron, ConocoPhilips, Eni, ExxonMobile, Shell, and Total) using all assets that started production between 1960 and 1999, leaving us with a total of 3494 assets. An asset represents a production site with at least one well, operated by at least one firm, and with the initial property right being owned by at least one country. Being able to conduct the analysis on the asset level is particularly valuable since it allows us to control for a large number of confounding factors and rule out several alternative explanations of our main finding.

Moreover, there are three advantages of focusing our analysis on the oil and gas sector in general and the oil majors in particular. First, the sunk investments in the development of oil and gas wells are enormous, making the hold-up problem in the oil sector particularly severe. Second, oil majors have been around for many years since all of them were created before WWII. This provides us with a sufficiently long horizon to capture backloading over time. Third, the majors are simultaneously investing in many countries which provides us the necessary cross-sectional variation in institutional quality. To differentiate between countries with weak and strong institutions, we use a specific dimension from the Polity IV dataset measuring the constraints on the executive. The location of all the assets disaggregated by firm as well as a binary distinction in a country’s institutional quality is shown in Figure 1.

Figure 1. Spatial distribution of assets and institutional quality

Note: Location and ownership of assets are provided by Rystad Energy. The executive constraint indicator is taken from Polity IV and we use the median from the period 1950 to 1975 to define whether the country is considered to have strong or weak institutions. The cut-off of 5 implies that roughly 1/3 of the countries are defined as having strong institutions and roughly 50% of all the assets which started operation between 1950 and 2000 are located in countries with weak institutions.

A Stylized Fact

For the empirical analysis, our variables of interest are investment, production and tax payments normalized by the respective asset-specific cumulative sum over a period of 35 years. The resulting cumulative shares are depicted in Figure 2. We focus on physical production which, in addition to being considered the most reliable measure of an asset’s activity, does not require discounting. Real values of investment and tax payment depict a very similar picture. Most importantly, the dashed lines illustrate that 2/3 of cumulative production shares are reached approximately two years earlier in countries with strong institutions, in comparison to countries with weak institutions. The average asset size does not differ significantly between these groups. Such delays are costly for countries with weak institutions. Our back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests that the average country loses around 120 million US$ per year due to the delayed production and the respective tax payments. We confirm that the two-year delay cannot be explained by geographical, geological or financial confounders such as the location of the well, fuel type or contract features.

Figure 2. Years to reach 66% of cumulative flows in 35 years

Note: We use the Epanechnikov kernel with an optimally chosen bandwidth to plot the cumulative production over the 35-year life span of the asset. We group countries into two groups with weak and strong institutions according to Polity IV. This figure contains assets that started producing between 1975 and 1999.

The Transition to a New World Order

To push towards a causal interpretation of the results, we exploit the global transition to a new world oil order. This change affected the probability of expropriations in countries with weak institutions while leaving countries with strong institutions unaffected. In particular, the post-WWII weakening of the OECD members as political and military actors provides a natural experiment of global proportions. Expropriations are first viewed as impossible due to the military threat of British, French and US armies, and then become possible due to a global movement aiming at returning sovereignty over natural resources to the resource-rich economies. In the words of Daniel Yergin (1993): “The postwar petroleum order in the Middle East had been developed and sustained under American-British ascendancy. By the latter half of the 1960s, the power of both nations was in political recession, and that meant the political basis for the petroleum order was also weakening. […] For some in the developing world […] the lessons of Vietnam were […] that the dangers and costs of challenging the United States were less than they had been in the past, certainly nowhere near as high as they had been for Mossadegh, [the Iranian politician challenging UK and US before the coup d’etat in 1953], while the gains could be considerable.” Consequently, the number of expropriations has grown substantially since 1968, marking the transition to a new world order (Figure 3). However, Kobrin (1980) finds that even during the peak of expropriations in 1960-1976, only less than 5 % of all foreign-owned firms in the developing countries were expropriated. We suggest that this is, at least partly, thanks to the use of backloaded self-enforcing contracts.

Figure 3. Transition to a new world order

Note: Data on firm expropriations across all industries from Kobrin (1984).

Indeed, focusing on the years around the transition to the new world oil order, we show that there have not been any differences in investment, production or tax payments dynamics between countries with weak and strong institutions in the early years of the 1960s. But investment, production and the payments of taxes started experiencing significant delays after 1968 in the countries with weak institutions, using countries with strong institutions as a control. Intuitively, the omnipresence of a credible military threat in response to an expropriation served as an effective substitute for strong local formal institutions and eliminated the need for contracts to be self-enforced and backloaded in countries with weak institutions. Once this threat disappeared, contracts had to be self-enforcing and investment, production and tax payments had to be backloaded to decrease the risk of being expropriated by the governments of resource-rich economies. Theoretically, these initial differences in contract backloading between countries with strong and weak institutions should disappear in the long run, because the future gains from trade need to materialize eventually. We confirm empirically that this point is reached on average 20 years after firms start a contractual relationship with a country.

Conclusion

We provide evidence that oil firms seem to backload contracts in countries with weak institutions. We show that such backloading appears in the data during the transition to a new world order since 1968, when firms were in need of a new mechanism to deal with weak property rights and the risk of expropriations. We estimate the cost of such delays to be around 120 US$ per country and year. While this cost is high, it is important to emphasize that in the absence of such backloading, forward-looking CEOs of oil majors would often choose not to invest in the first place, since they would anticipate the severe commitment problems (Cust and Harding, 2020). Thus, as a second-best, the cost of the backloading may be marginal compared to the value added from trade when oil majors are willing to invest in countries with weak institutions and questionable property rights.

References

 

[Postponed] Economic and Social Context of Domestic Violence

An image of broken glass representing perspectives of domestic violence

[Postponed until further notice]

The COVID-19 pandemic has amplified the academic and policy interest in the causes and consequences of domestic violence. With this in mind, the Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics (SITE) together with the Centre for Economic Analysis (CenEA) and the FREE Network will host a conference on the social and economic context of domestic violence.

Increases in Domestic Violence and “Shadow Pandemic”

Since the outbreak of Covid-19 in the spring of 2020, media outlets around the world have reported increases in domestic violence. United Nations secretary-general António Guterres has even referred to it as a “shadow pandemic”. Besides news outlets, academic researchers have also taken an interest in the issue, which is crucial to draw the right conclusions from the patterns visible in the statistics.

But more rigorous statistical analysis is needed for understanding not only the scale of domestic violence during the pandemic but also the broader socio-economic reasons which are behind this phenomenon in regular times, how it is perceived and what types of policies and regulations can be employed to limit it.

Conference and Keynote Lecture

The conference will combine presentations of academic papers and contributions from policy makers and interest groups. Both applied and theoretical contributions are welcome. The keynote lecturer will be Professor Bilge Erten (Northeastern University) and the conference is planned as a hybrid event with several sessions held at the Stockholm School of Economics and the entire program streamed online.

This event is organised as part of the Forum for Research on Gender Economics (FROGEE) supported by the Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency (Sida). 

Program and Registration

The full program and when the registration page will open will be announced soon.

202202012-pexels-anete-lusina-5723183-image-4-5

* Views represented during the events are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the FREE Network, or its institutes and partner organisations.

Call for Papers: “Economic and Social Context of Domestic Violence”

20220307 FROGEE conference Image 01

The Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics (SITE) together with the Centre for Economic Analysis (CenEA) and the FREE Network, invite academic contributions focusing on the economic and social context of domestic violence.

Call for Papers

The COVID-19 pandemic has amplified the academic and policy interest in the causes and consequences of domestic violence. With this in mind, SITE, CenEA and FREE Network will host a conference on 7 March 2022 entitled Economic and Social context of Domestic Violence.

Both applied and theoretical contributions are welcome by the submission of extended abstracts (1-2 pages).  Selected authors will have approximately 20 minutes for their presentations. Online submission is open via site@hhs.se. For applications please use the subject: Call for papers submission: Economic and social context of domestic violence. Download the Call for Papers announcement in pdf-version <here>.

The deadline for applications is 15 February 2022. Notifications are expected by 20 February 2022.

Conference

Since the outbreak of Covid-19 in the spring of 2020, media outlets around the world have reported increases in domestic violence. United Nations secretary-general António Guterres has even referred to it as a “shadow pandemic”. Besides news outlets, academic researchers have also taken an interest in the issue, which is crucial to draw the right conclusions from the patterns visible in the statistics.

But more rigorous statistical analysis is needed for understanding not only the scale of domestic violence during the pandemic but also the broader socio-economic reasons which are behind this phenomenon in regular times, how it is perceived and what types of policies and regulations can be employed to limit it.

The conference organised on 7 March 2022, will combine presentations of academic papers and contributions from policy makers and interest groups. The keynote lecturer will be Professor Bilge Erten (Northeastern University) and the conference is planned as a hybrid event with several sessions held at the Stockholm School of Economics and the entire program streamed online.

The event is organised as part of the Forum for Research on Gender Economics (FROGEE) supported by the Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency (Sida).

Registration

The full program and conference registration page will open in the following weeks.