Author: Admin
Increasing Resources for Families with Children Through the Tax System: Recent Reform Proposals from Poland
This brief discusses the consequences of a recent reform proposal that aims to redistribute resources to low-income families with children through the income tax system in Poland. The proposed reform replaces the current child tax credit with additional amounts of the universal tax credit, and by changing the sequence in which tax deductions are accounted for, it increases resources of low-income families with children by about 1.7 billion PLN per year (0.4 billion EUR). The brief examines four possible ways of additional tax system modifications that would make the reform package neutral for the public finances, and presents distributional implications of the reforms.
The level and structure of financial support for families with children has become an important policy focus in Poland; a country that faces high levels of child poverty and one of the lowest fertility rates in Europe (Immervoll et al., 2001; Haan and Wrohlich, 2011; Eurostat, 2013). In this brief, we outline recent tax reform proposals that aim to increase financial support for low-income families with children through the tax system. A range of such potential reforms has been examined in Myck et al. (2013b); a report prepared for the Chancellery of the President of the Republic of Poland. One of the options became the key element of the President’s family support program Better climate for families proposed in May 2013. Below we discuss its main features and various options for financing the proposals.
The proposed modification of financial support for families would replace the current child tax credit with additional amounts of the universal tax credit conditional on the number of children, and increase tax advantages for families by changing the sequence in which tax credits are accounted for in a way that is favorable for families with children (Chancellery of the President of Poland, 2013). The main beneficiaries of this reform would be low-income families with children whose income is too low to take full advantage of the current child-related advantages. The overall cost of the reform would amount to about 1.7 billion PLN (0.4 billion EUR). In the final section of the brief we discuss potential ways of making the reform budget neutral.
The analysis has been conducted using CenEA’s micro-simulation model SIMPL on reweighted and indexed data from the 2010 Household Budget Survey (HBS) collected annually by the Polish Central Statistical Office (see Morawski and Myck, 2010, 2011; Myck, 2009; Domitrz et al., 2013; Creedy, 2004).
Financial Support for Polish Families in 2013
In Poland, financial support for families with children depends on the level of family income and the demographic structure of the household. The system consists of two main elements – family benefits on the one hand, and tax preferences for families with children on the other. Following Myck et al. (2013a), we define financial support for a family j (FSFj) as the sum of family benefits received by the family (FBj), and tax preferences that families with children collect in the PIT system is defined as the difference in the level of tax liabilities and health insurance contributions paid by the family (PITHIjD0 – PITHIjDn) supposing they have no children (D0) and on condition them having n number of dependent children (Dn):
FSFj = FBj + (PITHIjD0 – PITHIjDn) [1]
Figure 1a presents the current level of the financial support for single-earner married couples and Figure 1b presents the same for single parents with one and three children in relation to the level of gross earnings.
Family benefits
Family benefits, which include family allowance with supplements, childbirth allowance and nursing benefits, are means-tested and related to the number and age of dependent children in the family and specific family circumstances. Family benefits are granted only to low-income families and are subject to point withdrawal once the family crosses the income eligibility threshold (539 PLN of net income per person). For example, the stylized married couples in Figure 1 lose family benefits when their monthly gross income exceeds 2,060 PLN if they have one child and 3,435 PLN if they have three children (for single parents these thresholds equal 785 PLN and 1,825 PLN respectively).
Figure 1. Monthly level of financial support received by families with one and three children dependent on their age and family gross income in 2013 (PLN/month) (a) Married couple with one spouse working b) Single parent working Note: FB – family benefits; CTC – child tax credit; joint taxation preferences: UTC – additional amount of universal tax credit; IB – shift of tax income bracket. In case of the single parent alimonies from the absent parent are assumed at the median value from 2010 data, which is 410.50 PLN for 1 child and 724.67 PLN for 3 children. Gross income of the single parent includes income from work only. Alimonies are taken into account for FB income means testing. Source: Myck et al. (2013a).Tax preferences
Taxpayers with children can deduct a non-refundable child tax credit (CTC) from the accrued tax, with the maximum values of the CTC related to the level of universal tax credit available to all tax payers (UTC is 46.37 PLN per month). For each of the first two children in the family, taxpayers can deduct up to two values of the UTC (92.67 PLN per month), for the third child up to three values (139.00 PLN per month) and for the fourth and following children up to four values of the UTC (185.34 PLN per month). The CTC is not available for high-income parents with one child (whose annual taxable income exceeds 112,000 PLN per year).
Further tax advantages are available for single parents through joint taxation, which translates into substantial gains in particular for high-income parents. As Figure 1 shows, single parents whose gross income exceeds the second tax income bracket (15,745 PLN per month) gain up to 1,044.19 PLN per month if they have one child and 1,368.54 PLN if they have three children. With the same income levels, the system grants nothing to married couples if they have one child and 324.34 PLN if they have three.
In the current system, the CTC can be deducted from the accrued tax only after the full amount of UTC and the tax-deductible part of health insurance (HI) contributions have been exhausted. As a consequence, there is a large group of low-income families whose income is too low to take full advantage of the CTC. As Figure 2 illustrates, the higher the number of children is in a family, the lower is the proportion of families who take full advantage of the credit. Although the percentage of those using the full CTC is 76.1% for families with one child, it decreases to 67.6% for those with two children and is as little as 30.8% for families with three or more kids. Over 40% of the latter use only half of the CTC they are entitled to.
Figure 2. Use of maximum amount of CTC by number of children Note: Proportions of families with taxable income satisfying other conditions for CTC. Source: Myck et al. (2013a).Recent Reform Proposals
In a recent report for the Chancellery of the President of Poland, we have analyzed several options for the reform of the family-related elements of the tax system (Myck et al., 2013b). One of these has become the key element of the presidential reform proposal (Chancellery of the President of Poland, 2013). The reform assumes that the CTC is replaced with the amounts of the Universal Tax Credit conditional on the number of children in the family in such a way as to maintain the current maximum advantages offered to families through the CTC system. The main purpose of the reform is to reverse the tax deduction sequence so that tax advantages related to having children are deducted from the accrued tax before considering credits related to health insurance contributions. Such construction would enable low-income families to make greater use of child-related tax advantages, while leaving the situation of higher-income families unchanged.
Figure 3. Monthly tax advantages from the reform among families with 1-4 children (PLN/month) Source: CenEA – own calculation based on SIMPL model and 2010 HBS data.Figure 3 presents monthly levels of tax advantages resulting from the proposed reform conditional on the number of children in the family and the level of gross income. We note that families with children gain from the reform if their income exceeds 735 PLN per month. Tax advantages resulting from the proposed modifications are exhausted at different levels of gross income depending on the number of children (from 2,630 PLN for families with one child to 8,010 PLN for those with four children). The higher the number of children is, the greater is also the potential maximum gain – for example, families with four children and income of 4,010 PLN per month would gain up to 311.35 PLN per month.
The results of the analysis show that, overall, 2 million households with children would benefit from this reform (below referred to as System 1). The total annual change in households’ disposable income (equivalent to the total cost for public finances) would amount to 1.69 billion PLN (see Table 1 below).
Table 1. Average annual change in households’ disposable income by number of children in Systems 1-5 (billion PLN)
No children |
1 child |
2 children |
3+ children |
Total |
|
System 1 |
0,00 |
0,39 |
0,60 |
0,70 |
1,69 |
System 2 |
-0,45 |
-0,20 |
0,04 |
0,55 |
-0,08 |
System 3 |
-0,65 |
-0,09 |
0,17 |
0,59 |
0,02 |
System 4 |
-0,66 |
-0,15 |
0,23 |
0,59 |
0,01 |
System 5 |
-0,86 |
-0,04 |
0,31 |
0,63 |
0,04 |
Table 1 shows that most of the resources would be beneficial for families with three or more children (0.7 billion PLN per year), while families with one or two children would benefit about 0.39 billion PLN and 0.6 billion PLN per year, respectively.
The distribution of total income gains by income deciles is presented in Figure 4. The gains are clearly focused in the lower part of the income distribution. For example, families with children in the second income decile would receive a total of 0.4 billion PLN, while those in the bottom and third decile would recieve approximately 0.25 billion PLN. Only 0.04 billion PLN of the total cost would be distributed to families in the top income decile.
Figure 4. Distribution of total annual gains in households’ disposable income by deciles: Systems 1-5 (billion PLN) Note: Total annual change in disposable income includes change in tax liabilities and level of social benefits. Source: Myck et al. (2013b).Potential Ways of Financing the Reform
Concerns about the state of public finances naturally imply questions related to the potential ways of financing any additional tax giveaways. Myck et al. (2013b) presents four alternative modifications of the tax system that make the entire package of reforms neutral for the public finances. These are:
- System 2 – CTC reform + limitations on joint-taxation preferences for married couples (both with or without children) and single parents;
- System 3 – CTC reform + reduction of tax income threshold from 85,528 to 68,000 PLN per year;
- System 4 – CTC reform + reduction of tax revenue costs from 1,335 to 475 PLN per year;
- System 5 – CTC reform + reduction of tax-deductible part of health insurance from 7.75% to 7.45%.
The overall total outcomes of these proposals for household disposable income are illustrated in Table 1 and Figure 4. The implications in terms of the redistribution of the packages – with losses among childless households and gains among those with children – are clear under all of the proposed packages, although all of the reform combinations imply small losses also for families with one child. Total disposable income of childless households falls by 0.45 PLN per year under System 2 and by as much as 0.86 billion PLN under System 5. By shifting the majority of the costs to households without children, the latter is simultaneously the most generous for families with children since income of those with two children grows on average by 0.31 billion per year, while of those with more children see a growth of 0.63 billion PLN per year.
Figure 4 illustrates that in all of the revenue neutral reform packages, the households from the highest two deciles are the biggest losers. That the financing of the shift of resources to low-income families falls on households from the top income decile is particularly evident in the case of Systems 2 and 3 where total disposal income for these households fall by 1.64 billion PLN and 1.52 billion PLN, respectively. Since changes to revenue costs and deduction of HI contributions apply to almost all taxpayers, Systems 4 and 5 are less favorable for households from the lower deciles and generate losses for the upper part of the income distribution. However, a large part of cost is also born by households from the tenth decile (0.26 and 0.39 billion PLN, respectively).
While the combinations of tax changes presented above would be neutral with respect to the current system of taxes in Poland, it is worth noting that the policy of tax increases through the tax-parameter freezing implemented in 2009 has increased taxes by far more than the cost of the Presidential reform proposal. As we showed in Myck et al. (2013c), this policy increased taxes by 3.71 billions PLN per year, of which 2.21 billions was paid by families with children. The recent proposal could thus be thought of as a way of redistributing these resources back to families with children.
Conclusions
Financial support for families with children is an important element of government policy with implications for child poverty, labor-market participation among parents, as well as fertility (Immervoll et al., 2001; Haan and Wrohlich, 2011). In this brief, we outlined the results of a recent analysis of direct financial consequences of modifications in the Polish system of support for families through the tax system with the focus on a reform proposal presented by the Polish President in the program Better climate for families. The reform would benefit lower-income families with children at the cost of about 1.7 billion PLN. As a result, annual income of the families from the three bottom deciles would grow by 0.93 billion PLN. A high proportion of the gains (0.7 billion PLN) would go to families with three or more children.
We also presented four additional modifications of the tax system that would make the CTC reform revenue neutral. Reform packages that withdraw joint-taxation preferences and decrease the threshold of the income tax to a higher rate would be most effective in ensuring redistribution of support for low-income households. It is worth noting though, that the recent approach of the Polish government to the tax system has implied substantial increases in the level of income taxes through the freezing of income tax parameters, and these alone would be more than sufficient to finance the proposed tax changes.
▪
References
- Creedy J. (2004). Reweighting Household Surveys for Tax Microsimulation Modelling: An Application to the New Zealand Household Economic Survey. Australian Journal of Labour Economics 7 (1): 71-88. Centre for Labour Market Research.
- Domitrz A., Morawski L., Myck M., Semeniuk A. (2013). Dystrybucyjny wpływ reform podatkowo-świadczeniowych wprowadzonych w latach 2006-2011 (Distributional effect of tax and benefit reforms introduced from 2006-2011). CenEA MR01/12; Bank i Kredyt 03/2013.
- Chancellery of the President of Poland (2013). Dobry klimat dla rodziny. Program polityki rodzinnej Prezydenta RP. (Better climate for families. Family support program of the Polish President.)
- Eurostat online database 2013 – epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu. Date of access: 28.11.2013.
- Haan P., Wrohlich K. (2011) Can Child Care Encourage Employment and Fertility? Evidence from a Structural Model. Labour Economics 18 (4), pp. 498-512.
- Immervoll H., Sutherland H., de Vos K. (2001). Reducing child poverty in the European Union: the role of child benefits. In: Vleminckx K. and Smeeding T.M. (eds.) Child well-being, Child poverty and Child Policy in Modern Nations. What do we know? The Policy Press: Bristol.
- Morawski L., Myck M. (2010).‘Klin’-ing up: Effects of Polish Tax Reforms on Those In and on Those Out. Labour Economics 17(3): 556-566.
- Morawski L., Myck M. (2011). Distributional Effects of the Child Tax Credits in Poland and Its Potential Reform. Ekonomista 6: 815-830.
- Myck M. (2009). Analizy polskiego systemu podatkowo-zasiłkowego z wykorzystaniem modelu mikrosymulacyjnego SIMPL (Analysis of the Polish tax-benefit system using microsimulation model SIMPL). Problemy Polityki Społecznej 11: 86-107.
- Myck M., Kundera M., Oczkowska M. (2013a). Finansowe wsparcie rodzin z dziećmi w Polsce w 2013 roku (Financial support for families with children in Poland in 2013). CenEA MR01/13.
- Myck M., Kundera M., Oczkowska M. (2013b). Finansowe wsparcie rodzin z dziećmi w Polsce: przykłady modyfikacji w systemie podatkowym (Financial support for families with children in Poland: examples of modifications in the tax system). CenEA MR02/13.
- Myck M., Kundera M., Najsztub. M, Oczkowska M. (2013c). Ponowne „mrożenie” PIT w kontekście zmian podatkowych od 2009 roku (PIT freezing in the context of tax reforms since 2009). Komentarze CenEA: 06.11.2013.
________________________________________________________________________________________________
* This brief draws on recent research at the Centre for Economic Analysis in the projects financed by the Chancellery of the President of the Republic of Poland and the Batory Foundation (project no: 22078). The analysis has been conducted using CenEA’s micro-simulation model SIMPL based on the 2010 Household Budget Survey data collected annually by the Polish Central Statistical Office (CSO). The CSO takes no responsibility for the conclusions resulting from the analysis. Any views presented in this brief are of the authors’ and not of the Centre for Economic Analysis, which has no official policy stance.
Integration Formations in the Monetary Sphere: the Possibility and the Necessity for Monetary Integration in the Post-Soviet Region
This policy brief addresses the possibility of monetary integration in the post-Soviet region. It provides a short overview of the literature devoted to the formation and development of the monetary unions, and argues that, based on this literature and real-world experiences, monetary integration can be of substantial value for the CIS states. However, such monetary union is not feasible in the near future due to weak economic integration of the national economies of the CIS countries, significant difference in their development level, and imbalances in allocation of bargaining power between the states. This policy brief suggests that a first step towards monetary integration could be an adoption of a supranational unit of account on the territory of the Customs Union between Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan.
The modern world has observed formation of a number of economic and monetary integration communities. Their performance varies greatly: some of them are developing successfully, others, on the contrary, are stagnating. Questions concerning the possibility of economic and monetary integration in the post-Soviet space are constantly addressed both by policymakers and by academic economists. Taking into account theoretical concepts and international experience, this brief addresses the possibility and desirability of the integration of the monetary sphere of the post-Soviet region. Based on Luzgina (2013a,b), this brief proposes a form of representation of monetary integration on the early stages of its development. In this case, an early form of monetary integration may be achieved via adoption of a single supranational unit of account on the territory of (a subset of) countries; the national currencies would continue to coexist with the new supranational currency. This approach to integration would allow preserving the independence of economic policy for the involved member states. At the same time, countries would benefit from a reduction in transaction costs and increasing convergence of national economies.
Background: Theoretical Concepts and World Experience of Monetary Integration
Ideally, the monetary union should have the form of an optimum currency area (OCA), a territory of one-currency domination with high level of integration and unification in different economic spheres. Modern economic science provides two main approaches considering the possibility of constructing an optimal currency zone on the territory of several states. The first suggests that optimality should be determined on the basis of implementing a specific group of criteria by countries. Among the main criteria, freedom of goods movement, labor and capital, openness and diversification of the economy, the synchronization inflation rates as well as integration in the financial sector can be mentioned. The second approach is based on a comparison of the benefits and costs in terms of the monetary union formation of the country with the highest economic potential. In practice, when studying the effectiveness of monetary integration, a synthesized approach is used. It includes evaluating by criteria, as well as taking into account costs and benefits that a country accrues in case of entering a particular monetary group. The main benefits of a monetary union include a reduction of transaction costs, trade relations enlargement, improving the discipline in the monetary sphere, and a reduction of the rate of international reserve sufficiency for every country-member. At the same time, there are some negative aspects of deep integration, such as loss of monetary policy independence, economic imbalances in case of weak convergence of national economies, loss of (part of) seigniorage income, and a possible negative public reaction to the adoption of a single currency.
When discussing the concept of monetary integration, it is important to understand the distinction between a monetary union and an optimum currency area. A monetary union is one of the most developed forms of a currency area, which implies a rigid anchor of national currencies to each other with a possible further transformation into the currency of the leading country, or to a single supranational currency (as in the case of the European Union). In this case, a monetary union can be formed of asymmetrical economies. Instead, the optimum currency area requires mandatory implementation of the main convergence criteria, and thereby, more symmetry/alignment among the members. Thus, a monetary union does not necessarily have to be an optimum currency area, while the optimum currency area has every opportunity to be transformed into a full-fledged monetary union [1].
Historically, there have been several examples of monetary union formations. The Italian monetary union (1862-1905), which was formed through the merger of disparate Italian lands, is among them. We can also identify the Scandinavian Monetary Union, which united Norway, Denmark and Sweden (1875-1917). The Austro-Hungarian monetary union existed in the period from 1867 to 1914. Currently, we observe formations of monetary unions in Africa, Latin America and the Arab states.
Despite the implementation of a number of integration projects within the various groups of countries over the past century, only the European states were able to achieve the highest form of monetary integration. It took them more than 50 years to do this, and the integration processes in the economic and monetary fields are continuing with new Member States joining the European Union. However, despite the detailed development plans for the implementation of a monetary union, the Eurozone countries face a number of difficulties and obstacles on the path of economic development. European monetary integration brings not only benefits, but also some costs. For example, the loss of independence of monetary policy creates obstacles in regulations of economic processes.
This discussion suggests that an assessment of the potential formation of a monetary union – that is, of desirability, feasibility and level of monetary integration within a particular group of countries – should be based on relating theoretical concepts and features of the countries in question, as well as a in-depth research of the experience of other currency unions.
Integration Processes in the Post-Soviet Space
At the territory of the former Soviet Union, integration projects have been implemented for more than 20 years. After the collapse of the Soviet Union, such integration formations as the Commonwealth of Independent States and the Eurasian Economic Community were created. Belarus, Kazakhstan and Russia have built a Customs Union (CU) and a Common Economic Space (CES). There is also a possibility of making a transition to the highest form of integration – a monetary union. However, this raises a number of questions: which CIS countries should join a monetary union, when should this be done, and what is the optimal form of monetary union for integrating countries.
Luzgina (2013b) shows that, within the framework of the CIS countries, that there are significant differences in many of the macroeconomic indicators. Countries differ in terms of GDP and the growth rates of investment and prices. For example, Belarus has the highest inflation in the post-Soviet region. The source of growth also differs: for example, a number of countries, such as Azerbaijan, Russia and Kazakhstan, owe a significant part of their economic growth to the availability of natural resources, but this is not universally true within the CIS. Dynamics of population income is also significantly different among the countries. Here, Russia occupies the leading position with its average wage at the beginning of 2012 reaching 780 USD. At the same time, in Tajikistan, the average wage amounts to only 110 USD.
Another concern is that the formation of an economic and monetary union implies free movement of labor and capital. However, at this stage of development, it can lead to some negative consequences. Free movement of labor could involve a massive flow of labor from depressed areas to regions where incomes are much higher. This may create pressure on health and social services in the latter regions. In turn, free movement of capital may cause speculative attacks on the financial markets. At the same time, the CIS countries, except Russia, Kazakhstan and Ukraine, do not have large gold reserves. Therefore, the free movement of capital flows without additional support may cause a crisis within the national financial systems. Out of all the gold reserves of the CIS countries, more than 85% of the total volume is owned by Russia. In the case of an abolition of restrictions on capital flows, countries that are exposed to speculative attacks are likely to ask Russia for help. Such a situation would require Russia to use its own financial resources, which would create an additional pressure on its international reserves.
Table 1. International reserves in the CIS countries, (million US dollars)
Country |
2008 |
2010 |
2012 |
Azerbaijan |
6467,2 |
6409,1 |
11277,3 |
Armenia |
1406,8 |
1865,8 |
1799,4 |
Belarus |
3063,2 |
5025,4 |
8095 |
Kazakhstan |
19883,1 |
28264,7 |
28299,4 |
Kirgizstan |
1225,1 |
1720,4 |
2066,7 |
Moldova |
1672,4 |
1717,7 |
2515 |
Russia |
426278,8 |
479222,3 |
537816,4 |
Tajikistan |
163,5 |
403,1 |
630,7 |
Ukraine |
31543,3 |
34571,3 |
24552,8 |
Russia is leading among the CIS countries in terms of population and territory, with other countries lagging substantially behind. For example, Belarus owns less than 1% of the total territory of the CIS countries and less than 4% of the population.
Relying on the above quantitative indicators it is natural to expect that in case of a formation of a monetary union with a single emission center, the distribution of votes in the decision-making of the development and implementation of monetary policy is likely to be unequal. The leading role would likely belong to Russia, which has the largest economic potential. However, other countries in this case may be in a less advantageous position as Russia’s decisions may lead to undesirable consequences for the economies of other countries, given the lack of a sufficient degree of synchronization of national economic systems.
Thus, a weak degree of economic integration of the national economies of the CIS countries, different levels of development, as well as the superiority of the economic potential of Russia over the other states gives reason to argue for a non-feasibility of monetary integration within the CIS countries in the short term.
On the other hand, it may be reasonable to consider the possibility of integration in the monetary sphere on the basis of the most economically integrated countries, namely Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan. These countries have created a Customs Union and are implementing a project of forming a Common Economic Space. There are plans of creating the Eurasian Economic Union. In addition, based on the experience of European countries, it might be easier to start the integration within a limited number of participants, which satisfy the required convergence criteria. Later, more countries may enter the monetary union.
Prospects for Monetary Integration of Belarus, Kazakhstan and Russia
Taking into account the experience of the European Union, we note the need for close trade and technological relations, as well as a market type of economy, and unification of the legislation in the economic sphere. Some of these elements of monetary integration are observed within the CU. After the collapse of the Soviet Union, economies of the former Soviet states switched to paths of market reforms. In addition, the CU countries have rather close trade relations; they have restored the old and created new means of communication. At the same time, there is a weak degree of diversification of exports and imports. A large part of export and import are represented by raw materials.
The second important point of the monetary integration is the comparability by size of the emerging economies. In the framework of the Customs Union, Russia is the only leader. Harmonization of relations between the alliance partners would be easier in the case of smaller countries coordinating their efforts, which would allow them to defend their interests along with the large member-states.
Finally, obligatory condition of monetary integration is the fulfillment of convergence indicators (certain values of macroeconomic indicators) by all association members. In Luzgina (2013b), we compare a range of such indicators, as based on the experience of the European Union. We use indicators such as the inflation rate, public debt, budget deficit, and the dynamics of exchange rates for comparison. The study reveals that the main differences lie in the monetary indicators, namely the rate of inflation and exchange rate. In addition, there are certain differences in the structure of the economy and the share of private ownership in GDP.
Figure 1. Exchange Rate (average for a year), as % of the previous year Figure 2. Industrial Producer Price Index (average for a year), as % of the previous year Source: Data of the Interstate Statistical Committee of the Commonwealth of the Independent StateThe persistence of significant differences in the values of convergence indicators at the macro level makes a full-fledged monetary union highly unlikely in the short term, even within the framework of the three most economically integrated states. At the same time, it is appropriate to consider the option of monetary integration in its mild form, i.e. in the form of monetary integration on the basis of a single unit of account. A single unit of account is usually calculated on the basis of the basket of national currencies, and is mostly used for international payments and credits.
The attractiveness of monetary integration in the form of monetary union on the basis of a supranational unit of account is motivated; first of all, by the preservation of the economic sovereignty of all countries. Circulation of the unit of account would take place in parallel with national currencies. Member states would retain the possibility of implementation of independent monetary and fiscal policies. Furthermore, the unit of account may fulfill the role of a training tool. The supranational payment unit can be used on the national level. Using this unit of account, legal entities may carry out transactions and individuals may hold their savings. It can also be actively implemented in the inter-state calculations. A part of gold and forex reserves of member countries can be held in the supranational unit of account. Inter-state loans can be issued in this unit as well. This type of monetary union would reveal the feasibility of further deepening of integration in the monetary sphere and determine the timing of the formation of a full-fledged monetary union. In case of serious problems, the dismantling of the currency union will not cause major adverse changes in national economies, unlike in the case of a collapse of a monetary union with a single currency. In addition, the operation of a single unit of account allows for the anticipation of potential problems associated with the functioning of economies under a single monetary system, and a solution before the introduction of a supranational currency.
Last, but not least, this form of integration seems to be a relatively feasible option as the process of convergence on the territory of the CU countries in the monetary sphere has already begun. There is an increased use of national currencies in bilateral trade, harmonization of national legislation is taking place in the monetary sphere, and international agreements in the monetary sphere are ratified. These activities are gradually building a base for the realization of the monetary integration project of the union countries.
Conclusions
Economic and monetary integration allows the countries to get the maximum benefit from mutual cooperation. However, the deepening of the integration process is usually accompanied by certain difficulties. Convergence of economic systems requires transformation of economic institutions, changes in legislation and principles of management, all of which are costly to achieve. The better the preliminary harmonization is performed, the easier the process of adaptation of national economies to function within a particular economic and monetary union will be.
The post-Soviet countries are implementing several projects of economic integration. However, their economies have major differences according to a number of macroeconomic indicators. The greatest degree of convergence is reached only by three CIS states, namely Belarus, Russia and Kazakhstan. Rather high level of economic integration, as well as a continuation of the process of unification and harmonization of national economies allows us to study the feasibility of realizing the lightweight form of a monetary integration based on a single supranational unit of account on the territories of Belarus, Kazakhstan and Russia.
▪
References
- Butorina O.V. International currencies: integration and competition / O.V. Butorina.- Мoscow.: Publishing house “Delovaia literatura”, 2003.- 368 p.
- Chapligin V.G. Theory and methodology of currency alliance formation/ V.G. Chapligin – St. Petersburg.: Publishing house SPbGUAF, 2003.- 193 p.
- Drobishevski S.M., Polevoi D.E. The problems of creating a single monetary zone in the CIS countries / S.M Drobishevski, D. I. Polevoi – Мoscow.: EAPP,- 2004. – 152 p.
- Euro – a baby of Mandell? The theory of optimum currency areas: collection of papers: translation from English.- Мoscow.: Delo, 2002.- 368 p.
- European monetary union: transition, international impact and policy options/ edited by Paul J.J. Welfens.- Berlin.- Springer.- 1997.-470 p.
- Eurasian Economic Community on-line database [Electronic resource]- Moscow.- 2005.- Mode of access: www.evrazes.com.- Date of access: 17.02.2012
- Evstigneev V.R. Currency and finance integration in EU and CIS. Comparative semantic analysis. /V.R. Evstigneev -М.: Наука.- 1997.—271 p.
- International monetary fund on-line database [Electronic resource] – Washington.- Mode of access: www.imf.org.- Date of access: 07.11.2012
- Kondratov D.I. Finantial integration: international experience and perspectives of CIS countries development/D.I. Kondratov// Economic Journal of HSE.- 2012.- №1.- p. 105-142.
- Luzgina A.N. Prospects of economic and monetary integration of the CIS member states/ A.N. Luzgina // Bank Bulletin Magazine. – 2013a.-№ 19 (600).- p. 21-26.
- Luzgina A.N. Model of monetary integration involving the Republic of Belarus / A.N. Luzgina // Bank Bulletin Magazine. – 2013b.-№ 20 (601).- p. 39-46.
- Mandell R. A theory of optimum currency areas/ R. Mundell// Interntional economics [Electronic resource].- New York: Macmillan.- 1968.- Mode of access: http://www.columbia.edu/~ram15/ie/ie-12.html. – Date of access: 23.05.2013.
- Monetary unions: theory, history, public choice/ edited by Forrest H. Capie and Geoffrey E. Wood.- London: Routledge, 2003.- 198 p.
- Statistical Committee of CIS on-line database [Electronic resource] – Мoscow, 2013.- Mode of access: www.cisstat.com.- Date of access: 03.09.2012
- Struk T. Concepts of reforming the world currency system/ Т. Struk// Bank Bulletin Magazine- 2012.-№16 [561].- p.7-14.
- World Bank on-line database [Electronic resource].- 2013.- Mode of access: http://worldbank.org.- Date of access: 27.06.2013
[1] Chapligin V.G. Theory and methodology of currency alliance formation/ V.G. Chapligin – St. Petersburg.: Publishing house SPbGUAF, 2003.- 193 p.
Can Public Enforcement of Competition Policy Increase Distortions in the Economy?
Authors: Vasiliki Bageri, University of Athens, Yannis Katsoulacos, Univeristy of Athens, and Giancarlo Spagnolo, SITE.
Competition law has recently been introduced in a large number of developed and emerging economies. Most of these countries adopted the common practice of basing antitrust fines on affected commerce rather than on collusive profits, and in some countries caps on fines have been introduced based on total firm sales rather than on affected commerce. Based on recent research, this policy brief explains how a number of large distortions are connected to these policies, which may facilitate competition authorities in their everyday job but at the high risk of harming the consumer and distorting industrial development. We conclude by discussing the possibility to depart from these distortive rules-of-thumb opened by recent advancements in data availability and econometric techniques, as well as by the considerable experience matured in estimating collusive profits when calculating damages in private antitrust litigation.
Competition policy has become a prominent policy in many developing economies, from Brazil to India. Indeed, the available evidence suggests that in countries where law enforcement institutions are sufficiently effective, a well designed and enforced competition policy can significantly improve total and labor productivity growth.
It is already well known that the private enforcement of competition policy can give rise to large distortions: since competition law is enforced by Judges and not by economist, it is easy for firms to strategically use the possibility to sue under the provision of competition law to protect their market position rather than the law being used to protect competition.
It is somewhat less known that a poor public enforcement of Competition Law by publicly funded competition authorities can also end up worsening market distortions rather than curing them. In the reminder of this policy brief we explain why, according to recent research, a mild and suboptimal enforcement of antitrust provisions – in the sense of fines that are too low to deter unlawful conduct (horizontal agreements and cartels in particular) and fines which are based on firm revenue rather than on the extra profits generated by the unlawful conduct, could significantly harm social welfare, even if we abstract from the direct cost the public enforcement of competition law imply for society.
Current Practice in Setting Fines
A very important tool for the effective enforcement of Competition Law is the penalties imposed on violators by regulators and courts. In this policy brief, we uncover a number of distortions that current penalty policies generate, we explain how their size is affected by market characteristics such as the elasticity of demand, and quantify them based on market data.
In contrast to what economic theory predicts, in most jurisdictions, Competition Authorities (CAs), but also courts where in charge, use rules-of-thumbs to set penalties that – although well established in legal tradition and in sentencing guidelines and possibly easy to apply – are hard to justify and interpret in logical economic terms. Thus, antitrust penalties are based on affected commerce rather than on collusive profits, and caps on penalties are often introduced based on total firm sales rather than on affected commerce.
A First Well Known Distortion Due to Legal Practice
A first and obvious distortive effect of penalty caps linked to total (worldwide) firm revenue is that specialized firms which are active mostly in their core market expect lower penalties than more diversified firms that are also active in several other markets than the relevant one. This distortion – why for God’s sake should diversified firms active on many markets face higher penalties than more narrowly focused firms? – could in principle induce firms that are at risk of antitrust legal action to inefficiently under-diversify or split their business to reduce their legal liability.
In a recent paper published in the Economic Journal, we examine two other, less obvious, distortions that occur when the volume of affected commerce is used as a base to calculate antitrust penalties.
A Second Distortion: Poorly Enforced Competition Law May Increase Welfare Losses from Monopoly Power
If expected penalties are not sufficient to deter the cartel, which seems to be the norm given the number of cartels that CAs continue to discover, penalties based on revenue rather than on collusive profits induce firms to increase cartel prices above the monopoly level that they would have set if penalties were based on collusive profits. Intuitively, this would be done in order to reduce revenues and thus the penalty. However, this exacerbates the harm caused by the cartel relative to a monopolized situation with similar penalties related to profits, or even relative to a situation with no penalties due to the distortive effects of the higher price and, in comparison to a situation with no penalties, the presence of antitrust enforcement costs.
A Third Distortion: Firms at the Bottom of the Value Chain May Pay a Multiple of the Fine Paid by Firms at the Top for an Identical Infringement
Firms with a high revenue/profit ratio, e.g. firms at the end of a vertical production chain, expect larger penalties relative to the same collusive profits that firms with a lower revenue/profit ratio would get. Our empirically based simulations suggest that the welfare losses produced by these distortions can be very large, and that they may generate penalties differing by over a factor of 20 for firms that instead should have faced the same penalty.
Note that this third distortion takes place also when at least for some industries fines are sufficiently high to deter cartels. This distortion means that competition is only enforced in industries that happen to be in the lower end of the production chain, and not in industries where the lack of competition is producing larger social costs. Note also that our estimation is based only on observed fines, i.e. on fines paid by cartels that are not deterred. Since cartels tend to be deterred by higher fines, this suggest that if we could take into account the fines that would have been paid by those cartels that were deterred (if any), the size of the estimated distortion would likely increase!
Concluding remarks
We argue that if one wants to implement a policy, one must be ready to do it well otherwise it may be better to not do it at all. This is particularly relevant for countries with weaker institutional environments where it is likely that political and institutional constraints will not allow for a sufficiently independent and forceful enforcement of the Competition Law.
It is worth noting that – in particular in the US but also increasingly so in the EU – the rules-of-thumb discussed above do not produce any saving in enforcement costs because the prescribed cap on fines requires courts to calculate firms’ collusive profits anyway. Furthermore, the distortions we identified are not substitutes where either one or the other is present. Instead, they are all simultaneously present and add to one another in terms of poor enforcement.
Where there are sufficient resources to allow for a proper implementation and where enforcement of Competition Law is available, developments in economics and econometrics make it possible to estimate illegal profits from antitrust infringements with reasonable precision, as regularly done to assess damages. It is time to change these distortive rules-of-thumb that make revenue so central for calculating penalties, if the only thing the distortions give us is savings in the costs of data collection and illegal profit estimation.
▪
Entrepreneurship in Latvia and Other Baltic States: Results from the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor
This policy brief summarises the results and implications of an upcoming Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) 2012 Latvia Report: a study on the entrepreneurial spirit and the latest trends in entrepreneurial activity in Latvia. The results suggest that Latvia is a rather entrepreneurial country (it rates second out of all EU countries by the share of population in early-stage entrepreneurial activity). GEM also finds that Latvian early-stage entrepreneurial activity is counter-cyclical. Early-stage entrepreneurship and self-employment have been important supports for those who were hit by the crisis in 2008-2009. Latvian entrepreneurs are measured to have strong international orientation and growth ambitions. The majority of them are young and middle-age males; in turn, females and the older age group (55-64) represent an “untapped entrepreneurial resource” potential to be addressed by policymakers.
Managed Competition in Health Insurance Systems in Central and Eastern Europe
This policy brief summarizes common trends in the development of health care systems in the Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Russia in late 1990s–early 2000s. These countries focused on regulated competition between multiple health insurance companies. However, excessive regulation led to various deficiencies of the model. In particular, improvements in such quality indicators of the three health care systems as infant and under-five mortality are unrelated to the presence of multiple insurers or insurer competition.
A number of transition countries in Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union introduced health care systems with compulsory enrollment, obligatory insurance contributions unrelated to need and coverage according to a specified package of medical services. This so-called social health insurance (SHI) model (Culyer, 2005) is regarded as a means for achieving universal coverage, stable financial revenues, and consumer equity (Balabanova et al. 2012; Gordeev et al., 2011; Zweifel and Breyer, 2006; Preker et al., 2002). While most transition countries chose to only have a single health insurance provider on the market, the Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Russia allowed competitive (and often private) insurers in the new system. However, the evidence from the three countries shows excessive regulation of health insurers and limited instruments for insurer competition within indebted post-reform health care systems (Naigovzina and Filatov, 2010; Besstremyannaya, 2009; Medved et al., 2005). Consequently, the three countries may have been over-enthusiastic in putting large emphasis on market forces in the reorganization of health care systems in economies with a legacy of central planning (Diamond, 2002).
This brief addresses the results of Besstremyannaya (2010), which assesses the impact of private health insurance companies on the quality of health care system. While various performance measures reflect different goals of national and regional health care systems (Joumard et al., 2010; Propper and Wilson, 2006; OECD, 2004; WHO, 2000), aggregate health outcomes directly related to the quality of health care are commonly infant and under-five mortality (Lawson et al., 2012; Gottret and Schieber, 2006; Wagstaff and Claeson, 2004; Filmer and Pritchett, 1999). Consequently, Besstremyannaya’s (2010) analysis regards mortality indicators as variables reflecting the overall quality of health care system.
The estimations employ data on Russian regions in 2000-2006. The results indicate that regions with only private health insurers have lower infant and under-five mortality. However, given the low degree of competition on the social health insurance market in Russia, we hypothesize that this effect is mostly driven by positive institutional reforms in those regions. Indeed, incorporating the effect of institutional financial environment, we find that the impact of private health insurers becomes insignificant.
Development of a Social Health Insurance Model in the Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Russia
At the beginning of their economic transition, the Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Russia established a model for universal coverage of citizens by mandatory health insurance (Balabanova et al., 2012; Medved et al., 2005; Sheiman, 1991). The revenues of the new SHI system came from a special payroll tax and from government payments for health care provision to the non-working population. The main reason for combining certain features of taxation-based and insurance-based systems was the desire to establish mandatory health insurance as a reliable source of financing in an environment with unstable budgetary revenues (Lawson and Nemec, 2003; Preker et al., 2002; Sheiman, 1994). The insurance systems instituted in the three transition countries correspond to the major SHI principles implemented in Western Europe: contributions by beneficiaries according to their ability to pay; transparency in the flow of funds; and free access to care based on clinical need (Jacobs and Goddard, 2002).
The Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Russia placed emphasis on regulated competition, decreeing that SHI should be offered by multiple private insurance companies with a free choice of the insurer by consumers. Managers of private insurance companies were assumed to perform better than government executives (Lawson and Nemec, 2003; Sinuraya, 2000; Curtis et al., 1995), so an intermediary role for private insurance companies was seen as a key instrument for introducing market incentives and improving the quality of the health care system (Sheiman, 1991).
However, the activity of health insurance companies in the three countries was heavily regulated, since the content of benefit packages, size of subscriber contributions, and the methods of provider reimbursement were decided by government, and tariffs for health care were frequently revised (Lawson et al., 2012; Rokosova et al., 2005; Zaborovskaya et al., 2005; Praznovcova et al., 2003; Hussey and Anderson, 2003). In particular, Russian health care authorities enforced rigid assignments of areas, whose residents were to be served by a particular health insurance company (Twigg, 1999) and imposed informal agreements with health insurance companies to finance providers regardless of the quality and quantity of the health care (Blam and Kovalev, 2006). As a result, the three countries experienced an initial emergence of a large number of health insurance companies, followed by mergers between them, resulting in high market concentration (Sergeeva, 2006; Zaborovskaya et al., 2005; Medved et al., 2005).
In Russia, the Health Insurance Law (1991) specified that until private insurers appeared in a region, the regional SHI fund or its branches could play the role of insurance companies. Therefore, several types of SHI systems emerged in Russian regions in the 1990s and early 2000s: the regional SHI fund might be the only agent on the SHI market; the regional SHI fund might have branches, acting as insurance companies; SHI might be offered exclusively by private insurance companies; or SHI might be offered by both private insurance companies and branches of the regional SHI fund (Figure 1). The variety of SHI systems reflects the fact that many regions opposed market entry by private insurance companies (Twigg, 1999). Indeed, the boards of directors of regional SHI funds usually included regional government officials (Tompson, 2007; Tragakes and Lessof, 2003) who were reluctant to reduce government control over SHI financing sources (Blam and Kovalev, 2006; Twigg, 2001). The controversy with health insurance legislation created a substantial confusion at the regional and the municipal level (Danishevski et al., 2006).
Figure 1. Health insurance agents in Russia in 2000-2006, (number of regions)This context suggests that Russian regions provide an interesting study field to address the impact of private health insurance companies on the quality of health care system. In particular, the wide variety of SHI systems across Russian regions, as well as the gradual introduction of the health insurance model in Russia provide a sufficient degree of variation in practices and outcomes to allow for a well-specified empirical analysis.
Data and Results
In our analysis we use data on Russian regional economies between 2000 and 2006 (as based on data availability). Our measures of health outcomes are given by the pooled regional data on infant and under-five mortality. Our key explanatory variable is the presence of only private health insurers in the region. Arguably, the coexistence of public and private health insurance companies does not enable effective functioning of private health insurers owing to their discrimination by the territorial health insurance fund. Therefore, in the empirical estimations we focus on the presence of only private health insurers in the region, regarding it as a measure of effective health insurance model. The analysis also employs a variety of important socio-economic and geographic variables influencing health outcomes (per capita gross regional product (GRP), share of private and public health care expenditure in gross regional product, share of urban population, average temperature in January).
The results of the first set of our empirical estimations demonstrate that the presence of only private health insurers in a region leads to lower infant and under-five mortality. Furthermore, an increase in the share of private health care expenditure in GRP leads to a decrease in both mortality indicators. The result is consistent with numerous findings about the association between personal income and health status in Russia (Balabanova et al., 2012; Sparling, 2008).
Prospective reimbursement of health care providers is associated with a decrease in infant and under-five mortality. The finding suggests the existence of a quasi-insurance mechanism in the Russian SHI market. Operating in an institutional environment where provider reimbursement is based on prospective payment, private insurance companies in effect shift a part of their risk to providers (Glied, 2000; Sheiman, 1997; Chernichovsky et al., 1996).
Table 1. Factors leading to decreased infant and under-five mortality in Russia Notes: * indicates that the coefficient is statistically significant in a parametric regressionAlthough our analysis shows that the presence of only private health insurers is statistically associated with improvements in infant and under-five mortality, we believe that the influence is indirect. Namely, the overall positive institutional environment in the region may result in both a decrease of mortality indicators and a lower coercion of regional authorities towards the presence of private health insurance companies.
To test this hypothesis, we use financial risk in a region as a measure of institutional environment and incorporate it in the analysis through an instrumental variable approach. (We measure financial risk by an expertly determined rank ordered variable by RA expert rating agency; this variable reflects the balance of the budgets of enterprises and governments in the region, with lower ranks corresponding to smaller risk.)
In line with our hypothesis, the results suggest that the presence of private health insurance companies now becomes insignificant in explaining infant and under-five mortality.
Discussion
The existing literature suggests that the improvement in infant and under-five mortality in the Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Russia can be attributed primarily to an increase of health care spending (Gordeev et al. 2011; Besstremyannaya, 2009; Lawson and Nemec, 2003) rather than being an effect of the social health insurance model with multiple competing insurers. It should be noted that insufficient government payments for the non-working population and a decline of the gross domestic product in the early transition years left SHI systems in the three countries indebted (Naigovzina and Filatov, 2010; Sheiman, 2006; Medved et al., 2005), which undermined the development of the managed competition in the health care provision.
In Russia (and also in the Czech Republic and Slovakia) there is little competition between insurers, and surveys show that the main factors causing consumers to change their health insurance company are change of work or residence, and not dissatisfaction with the insurer (Baranov and Sklyar, 2009). The fact that law suits on defense of SHI patient rights are rarely submitted to courts through health insurers (Federal Mandatory Health Insurance Fund, 2005) may also be evidence of the failure of Russian health insurance companies to win customers on the basis of their competitive strengths.
Summary and Policy Implications
The above findings as well as the other mentioned literature suggest that improvements of infant and under-five mortality in the Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Russia are not associated with the positive role of managed competition in the social health insurance system. In particular, in Russia the decrease in infant and under-five mortality is likely to be related to financial environment, rather than the existence of insurance mechanisms or competition between health insurance companies. One possible explanation of this absence of effect may come from the excessive regulation of the private insurance markets, as well as the insufficient competition between insurers. Importantly, the health insurance reform, implemented in Russia in 2010, both addressed underfinancing (by raising payroll tax rates) and took a step towards fostering provider competition, by allowing private providers to enter the social health insurance market (Besstremyannaya 2013). However, insurance companies are still not endowed with effective instruments for encouraging quality by providers, which may greatly undermine their efficiency.
▪
References
- Balabanova D, Roberts B, Richardson E, Haerpfer C, McKee V. 2012. Health Care Reform in the Former Soviet Union: Beyond the Transition. Health Services Research 47(2): 840-864.
- Baranov IN, Sklyar TM. 2009. Problemy strakhovoi modeli zdravookhraneniya na primere Moskwy i Sankt-Peterburga (Problems of insurance model in health care: the example of Moscow and Saint Petersburg). In X International Conference on the Problems of Development of Economy and Society, Yasin E.G (ed), Moscow: Higher School of Economics, vol.2.
- Besstremyannaya GE. 2013. Razvitie systemy obyazatelnogo meditsinskogo strakhovaniya v Rossijskoi Federatsii (Development of the Mandatory Health Insurance system in the Russian Federation) Federalizm 3: 201-212
- Besstremyannaya GE. 2010. Essays in Empirical Health Economics. PhD thesis. Keio University (Tokyo).
- Besstremyannaya GE. 2009. Increased public financing and health care outcomes in Russia. Transition Studies Review 16: 723-734.
- Blam I, Kovalev S. 2006. Spontaneous commercialization, inequality and the contradictions of the mandatory medical insurance in transitional Russia. Journal of International Development 18: 407–423.
- Culyer AJ (2005) The Dictionary of Health Economics, Edward Elgar.
- Danishevski K, Balabanova D, McKee M, Atkinson S. 2006. The fragmentary federation: experiences with the decentralized health system in Russia. Health Policy and Planning 21: 183–194.
- Gordeev VS, Pavlova M, Groot W. 2011. Two decades of reforms. Appraisal of the financial reforms in the Russian public healthcare sector. Health Policy 102(2-3): 270-277.
- Hussey P, Anderson GF. 2003. A comparison of single- and multi-payer health insurance systems and options for reform. Health Policy 66: 215-228.
- Jacobs R, Goddard M. 2002. Trade-offs in social health insurance systems. International Jthenal of Social Economics 29(11): 861-875.
- Lawson C, Nemec J, Sagat V. 2012. Health care reforms in the Slovak and Czech Republics 1989-2011: the same or different tracks? Ekonomie a management 1, 19-33.
- Lawson C, Nemec J. 2003. The political economy of Slovak and Czech health policy: 1989-2000. International Political Science Review 24(2): 219-235.
- Medved J, Nemec J, Vitek L. 2005. Social health insurance and its failures in the Czech Republic and Slovakia: the role of the state. Prague Economic Papers 1:64-81.
- Praznovcova L, Suchopar J, Wertheimer AI. 2003. Drug policy in the Czech Republic. Jthenal of Pharmaceutical Finance, Economics and Policy 12(1): 55-75.
- Preker AS, Jakab M, Schneider M. 2002. Health financing reforms in Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, in Funding Health Care: Options for Europe, Mossalos E., Dixon A., Figueras J., Kutzin J. (Eds.), European Observatory on Health Care Systems Series: Open University Press, 2002.
- Rokosova M, Hava P, Schreyogg J, Busse R. 2005. Health care systems in transition: Czech Republic. Copenhagen, WHO Regional Office for Europe on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies.
- Sheiman I. 1991. Health care reform in the Russian Federation. Health Policy 19: 45–54.
- Sheiman I. 2006. O tak nazyvaemoi konkurentnoi modeli obyazatelnogo meditsinskogo strahovaniya (On so-called competitive model of mandatory health insurance). Menedzher Zdravoohraneniya 1: 52-58.
- Sheiman I. 1997. From Beveridge to Bismarck: Health Financing in the Russian Federation’. In Innovations in Health Care Financing, Schieber G. (ed.), Discussion Paper 365, 1997, Washington DC: The World Bank.
- Sinuraya T. 2000. Decentralization of the health care system and territorial medical insurance coverage in Russia: friend or foe? European Jthenal of Health Law 7:15–27.
- Sparling AS. 2008. Income, drug, and health: evidence from Russian elderly women. PhD dissertation. University North Carolina at Chapel Hill, UMI Dissertations Publishing.
- Tompson W. 2007. Healthcare reform in Russia: problems and perspectives. Working Papers 538, OECD Economics Department
- Tragakes E, Lessof S. 2003.Russian Federation, Health Care Systems in Transition, The European Observatory, WHO, Europe.
- Twigg J. 1999. Obligatory medical insurance in Russia: the participants’ perspective. Social Science and Medicine 49: 371–382.
- Twigg, JL. 2001. Russian healthcare reform at the regional level: status and impact. Post-Soviet Geography and Economics 42: 202–219.
- Zaborovskaya AS, Chernets VA, Shishkin SV. 2005. Organizatsiya upravleniya i finansirovaniya zdravoohraneniyem v subjektah Rossijskoi Federatsii v 2004 godu (Organization of management and finance of healthcare in Russian regions in 2004)
- Zweifel P, Breyer F. The economics of social health insurance. In The Elgar Companion to Health Economics, Jones A. (ed.), Edward Elgar, 2006.
- Wagstaff A. 2010. Social health insurance reexamined. Health Economics 19: 503–517.
Decomposition of Economic Growth in Belarus
During the last decade Belarus was one of the leaders of growth in the CEE region. Kruk and Bornukova (2013) have analyzed the sources of growth and found that capital accumulation was the main contributor to growth. The contribution of total factor productivity (TFP) to growth was, on the contrary, quite modest. On the sectoral level, capital accumulation was not always accompanied by the increases in TFP. Hence, the new growth policy, modernization, with the bottom line “more capital” may not be the best option for enhancing productivity-based growth. The competitive advantages of Belarus lie in the resource-based and non-tradable sectors, while the majority of the manufacturing sectors are lagging behind in productivity. Belarus has symptoms of a Dutch disease without the trade surplus, and the devaluation of 2011 did not cure it.
During 2003-2012, Belarus had an average growth rate of 7.1%, and during the ‘fat years’, i.e. 2003-2008, it was even higher – 9.5%. Intuitively, this prominent growth is questionable, as it was achieved in the context of dominating state ownership, centralized allocation of resources, government’s control at the factor and goods markets, as well as poor infrastructural reforms (for instance, according to the indices of the EBRD). The Belarusian case challenges the mainstream paradigm of growth in transitional countries, which assumes that the progress in market reforms is the key factor for high and sustainable growth.
The simplest and most widespread explanation of the Belarusian phenomena is based on ‘non-standard’ gains in productivity. This approach assumes that productivity is the engine of growth (World Bank (2012); Demidenko and Kuznetsov (2012)). To a large extent, these gains in productivity are seen as “artificial”, resulting from Russian injections into the Belarusian economy: cheap gas, specific schemes of oil trade, and preferences in access to the Russian markets (Kruk (2010)). However, under this approach, decomposing the growth in productivity by ‘natural’ and ‘artificial’ parts is hardly possible, as the impact of these factors is already hidden in the available data.
The IMF (2010) gave a substantially different explanation of Belarusian growth. They claimed that the average growth of 8.3% over the period of 2001-2008 was mainly capital-based with a contribution of 4.8 percentage points, while the contribution of productivity growth was only 3.0 percentage points (the rest of growth was explained by labor and cyclical factors).
The main reason behind the substantial difference in the explanation of growth factors is the statistical data on capital used during the growth accounting exercise. Belarusian official statistics reports the data on capital stock based on a direct survey of capital assets according to both gross and net (wealth) capital concept. However, the growth rates of capital are reported only for the gross stock of capital. These growth rates are questionable as they demonstrate ‘unnatural stability’ – they fluctuate around 2% for the last 20 years, despite the fact that investments during this period has displayed huge and volatile growth. Statistical offices in other CIS countries have reported similar dynamics of the capital stock. Voskoboynikov (2012), and Bessonov and Voskoboynikov (2008) show that this trend is a consequence of the statistical methodology used in Russia (which the Belarusian methodology is very similar to). In particular, the trend is driven by biased capital investments deflators (which are overestimated) from the periods of high inflation (1990-s and early 2000-s).
If official data is used as the capital input for the growth accounting exercise, the contribution of TFP to growth will be overestimated. Hence, in the studies of the World Bank (2012) and Demidenko and Kuznetsov (2012), the leading role of TFP may be due to the use of the official data on the capital stock.
Motivated by this concern, we use two different methods to evaluate the value of capital inputs (see Kruk and Bornukova (2013) for more details). The first alternative to using the data from direct capital survey is to exploit a perpetual inventory method (PIM): the historical assessment of initial capital stock is further adjusted by the flow of investments and depreciation. However, if there is a bias in deflators within the sample, the series will also be distorted. This problem may be eliminated if the initial stock will be selected at the moment when there is no bias in investment deflator, in the period of moderate inflation. We call this approach PIM-backward.
The second approach to constructing capital series exploits the concept of productive capital and the data on the flow of capital. It assumes that the productive capacity of a capital good depends on its age. The productive stock of a capital good (i.e. the gross stock adjusted by the age-efficiency profile) generates a flow – capital services. The latter is the productive stock adjusted by the user cost of the individual capital good. For the total output of an industry (or economy) one should aggregate the inputs by different capital goods, which in contrast to the net (wealth) concept depends not only on the value of capital goods, but also on their user costs. This approach has solid theoretical foundations, which is the reason it is prioritized in productivity studies.
From the view of available data in the case of Belarus, this approach has a number of powerful advantages. First, we use individual deflators for individual capital goods, which are expected to be less biased than total deflators for the industry. Second, we use heterogeneous depreciation rates for each capital good in each industry based on actual data of ‘accounting depreciation’, while we would have to use homogenous assumptions for each industry in the case of net (wealth) concept. Third, we can exclude residential housing from our measure of capital input.
There are, however, also disadvantages. First, data of newly employed capital goods (in direct surveys of capital assets) and data on capital investments differ rather substantially. Traditionally, the data on capital investments is treated as more reliable, but based on the direct surveys of capital assets we have to use the series of newly employed capital goods as a flow variable when running PIM. Second, we use exogenous real interest rate for computing unit user costs, but the results are very sensitive to our assumptions on the real interest rates across industries. Third, the necessity to exclude residential housing from the data (because of ‘mixed historical prices’) may be interpreted as a loss of information. Given the strengths and weaknesses of the approach, we prioritize it on the industrial level, but prefer the PIM-backward approach for an aggregate economy analysis.
Based on the PIM-backward measure for the total economy (see Figure 1), we may argue that the contribution of TFP to growth was more modest during the last decade than what was reported in the majority of previous studies on Belarusian growth. This finding is of fundamental importance for the growth agenda: only productivity-based growth may be treated as sustainable, since capital growth will slow down as the capital approaches its stationary value. We argue that only the policy directed to promotion of productivity is vital for growth prospects.
Figure 1. Contribution of Production Factors and TFP to the Growth of Gross Value Added (PIM-Backward Approach)The dynamics of productivity divided according to industries (see Table 1) display that the leaders in productivity growth are either industries that produce non-tradable goods (communications, finance, construction) or those that have a chance of ‘artificial productivity gains’ (chemical and petrochemical manufacturing, and fuel).
Table 1. Initial Level and Growth Rates of Productivity in Major IndustriesHowever, the theory suggests that the leaders in productivity growth should be the industries producing tradable goods. . This contradiction may be interpreted in two ways. First, one may argue that a more competitive environment and larger share of private ownership (which are seen in the financial industry, trade and catering) are the core reasons for high productivity level and growth rates in ‘domestic industries’. Second, an attractive position of ‘domestic industries’ may reflect a high level of domestic prices rather than ‘natural’ productivity. The base year for our computations is 2009, in which both the real effective exchange rate of the national currency and income were relatively high. The devaluation of 2011 fixed the problem only temporarily, since the inflation in 2011-2013 quickly eroded the benefits of the devaluation. Therefore, the indicators, in terms of 2009 prices, may capture the changes in nominal values as the main component of the productivity gains, while from a longer-term perspective it would be seen as mainly price movements without substantial progress in productivity. In our view, the second explanation is the main reason for the non-standard disposition of productivity levels and growth rates among industries.
If that is the case, the bigger picture looks as follows. Industries producing tradable goods suffer from the lack of progress in productivity, i.e. lose their competitive advantage; enhancements in total productivity are mainly due to industries with ‘artificial productivity gains’. The latter allows domestic prices to grow, making a productivity illusion of domestic industries. All together these symptoms are quite similar to the Dutch disease.
One more finding from the productivity analysis at the national level is the lack of productivity gains from reallocation of resources from less productive industries to more productive ones. A scatter-plot between capital accumulation growth rates and TFP growth rates (see Figure 2) demonstrates no clear relationship between them.
Figure 2. Growth Rates of Capital Input vs. TFP Growth Rates in Manufacturing Branches, 2006-2010.Notes: The sizes of the circles correspond to industry shares in value added.
However, if there was a free allocation of resources, more productive industries would accumulate more capital. Moreover, the same indicators under the PIM-backward approach demonstrate clear negative relationship. A ‘soft’ interpretation of this phenomenon assumes that the lack of reallocation of capital restrains the development of total productivity. A ‘tighter’ interpretation assumes that at least in some industries there is a trade-off between capital accumulation and productivity gains. For instance, in Kruk and Haiduk (2013) it is shown that spurring capital accumulation through the practice of directed lending leads to losses in efficiency through a number of channels. Hence, the simplest way to increase aggregate productivity is to depart from the centralized allocation of capital and unblock capital inflows to more productive industries and vice versa.
Figure 3 documents the mobility of labor markets across the manufacturing industries in Belarus. While one can expect that labor flow into more productive industries, it is not completely true for the Belarusian manufacturing sector.
Figure 3: Labor growth and TFP growth in industries of Belarusian manufacturing, (capital services approach).Notes: The sizes of the circles correspond to industry shares in value added.
Two distinct trends emerge in the labor market. On the one hand, some industries exhibit textbook behavior: increases in TFP are associated with increases in the number of people employed. The best example here is the fuel industry, which experiences TFP increases due to preferential oil prices. However, there are industries that gain TFP and lose labor at the same time. The chemical industry, machinery manufacturing and woodworking are examples of this pattern. These industries have experienced rapid capital accumulation, which, coupled with high gains in TFP, should have contributed to the increases in labor productivity. Surprisingly, though, these industries did not attract more labor. A possible explanation for this counterintuitive pattern is the excessive employment at the beginning of the period in question. In this case, a decrease in the number of people employed may have contributed to the increases of TFP.
Indeed, Figure 4 confirms our hypothesis: labor was flowing from the industries with lower labor productivity to the industries with higher labor productivity in general. Industries in which TFP increased and which were accompanied by a labor decrease, featured low labor productivity in the beginning of the period in consideration, more precisely in 2005. Only the chemical industry exhibited the unexpected behavior: it lost labor despite high initial productivity. By getting rid of excessive employment they were contributing to an increase in TFP.
Figure 4: Labor shifts into the sectors with higher labor productivity.Notes: The sizes of the circles correspond to industry shares in value added.
How is Belarus doing relative to other countries? We have compared Belarusian TFP to the TFP of the leader of transition, the Czech Republic, and to the regional leader, Sweden. The Czech Republic is more developed than Belarus (in 2010 Czech GDP per capita (PPP-corrected) was 1.73 times higher than in Belarus), and, theoretically, it should be much more difficult and costly for it to continue approaching the technological frontier. However, our findings suggest that the Czech Republic is catching up with Sweden in terms of TFP, and doing it faster than Belarus (see Figure 5).
Figure 5: TFP of Belarus and the Czech Republic relative to TFP of Sweden, (PIM-backward approach).Over the last 10 years, Belarus has closed only 5 percentage points of the gap with Sweden. The Czech Republic, where the contribution of TFP to growth was more substantial, has managed to close 8 percentage points of the gap.
In absolute numbers (in ‘international’ dollars of 2010), aggregate TFP in Belarus in 2010 was 2.92 versus 4.66 in the Czech Republic and 9.38 in Sweden (according to the PIM-backwards method). However, the aggregate picture does not reflect the situation in the sectors of the economy and industries of manufacturing.
Table 2: Comparative advantage of Belarusian industries: winners and losers (capital services approach)Table 2 documents the comparative advantages and disadvantages of the Belarusian economy in 2010 according to the capital services approach. Both the capital services approach and the PIM-backwards approach produce the same winners and losers list with the only difference being that the PIM-backwards method has the construction sector among winners. It is not surprising to see resource-based industries among the winners (mining and quarrying mainly reflects the extraction of potash, while the chemical industry benefits both from potash and from preferential process for Russian oil). Food manufacturing is among the winners mostly due to the price scissors in agriculture: food producers buy their inputs at very low prices. The non-tradable sectors are among winners, and the majority of the manufacturing sectors are among the losers. Again, this is similar to the symptoms of the Dutch disease. It is ironic that Belarus has symptoms of a Dutch disease without the trade surplus. Instead, the desire of the government to inflate wages combined with the preferences for Russia led to the development of the same diagnosis.
Belarusian economic growth is less TFP-led than is commonly believed. While the labor market proves to be relatively successful in its reallocation of employees and its contribution to aggregate increases in efficiency, the capital market is distorted by government interventions. Capital accumulation does not necessarily lead to increases in TFP, and the new modernization policy with the bottom line of “more capital” may not be the best option for enhancing growth. Our conclusion is that Belarus should find new sources for TFP-led growth.
▪
References
- Bessonov, V., Voskoboynikov.I. (2008). “Fixed Capital and Investment Trends in the Russian Economy in Transition.”, Problems of Economic Transition, 51(4), pp. 6-48.
- Demidenko, M., Kuznetsov, A. (2012). “Ekonomicheskiy rost v Respublike Belarus: factory i otsenka ravnovesiya” (Economic Growth in Belarus: Factors and Equilibrium Assessments), National Bank of the Republic of Belarus, Working Paper No.3.
- IMF (2010). “Sources of Recent Growth and Prospects for Future Growth”, IMF, Country Report No.10/16.
- Kruk, D., Bornukova, K. (2013). “Belarusian Economic Growth Decomposition”, unpublished manuscript.
- Kruk, D., Haiduk, K. (2013). “The Outcome of Directed Lending in Belarus: Mitigating Recession or Dampening Long-Run Growth?”, BEROC Working Paper Series, WP No.22
- Kruk, D. (2010). “Vliyanie krizisa na perspectivy dolgosrochnogo ekonomisheskogo rosta v Belarusi” (The Impact of Crisis on the Perspectives of Long-term Growth in Belarus), IPM Research Center Working Paper Seies, WP/10/07.
- World Bank (2012). “Belarus Country Economic Memorandum: Economic Transformation for Growth”, Country Economic Memorandum, Report No. 66614
- Voskoboynikov, I. (2012). “New Measures of Output, Labour and Capital in Industries of the Russian Economy”, Groningen Growth and Development Centre, Research Memorandum GD
Some More Reflections on RCTs
In preparation of next year’s elections, the Swedish government chose recently to replace the Minister for International Development Cooperation. During her long mandate, former Minister Gunilla Carlsson championed the importance of aid evaluation and result focus, and managed to move aid from a quiet consensus to become a hotly debated topic. She also closed down the aid evaluation agency SADEV, following the publication of critical reviews about the work of the agency. Now, an expert group is in charge of rethinking and redesigning development policy evaluation and planning. One of the tools under consideration is randomized control trials (RCTs). This is an area in which Swedish development cooperation has no previous experience. Here are some reflections on RCTs.
In recent years, the methods of development economics have been crucially altered by the introduction of randomized control trials (RCTs). The idea behind RCTs is that development policies can be evaluated similarly to clinical trials in medicine, where subjects are randomly assigned to receive a treatment or to function as a reference or control group. The main benefit of this approach is that the random assignment allows for an estimation of the effect of the treatment (that is, the policy in question), while avoiding unobservable confounding factors or selection issues (see more about the advantages of the method in Banerjee et al. (2008)).
The diffusion of experimental methods in development economics has undoubtedly been a revolution in the academic and, if not yet fully, in the policy world. In the blogosphere there has even been talk of awarding Sveriges Riksbank’s Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel, informally called the Nobel Prize of Economics, to the MIT couple Banerjee – Duflo. Due to their young age and the closeness in time of their contribution, this would be a ”shock” prize meant to give a strong signal. Their creation, the Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab (J-PAL), stands for a new approach to both scientific and policy work in development that is a fantastic contribution, and definitely has the connotation of seminal.
However, it might be too early for the profession to sanction a method that has much good to show for, but also potentially undesired consequences. In the camp of critics there are heavy weights such as Angus Deaton and Dani Rodrik of Princeton, and the World Bank’s Philip Keefer and Martin Ravallion. The core of their position is of course not to deny the merits of RCTs, but to advocate their use in the right way and, in particular, as one tool among many others, with important complementarities to the others.
Some points in this context are often made, well understood and widely accepted: the limits of the approach per se, in particular the problem of external validity (the question of how generally applicable are the findings from such studies); the conflict between short-run and long-run implications, especially with respect to some policy areas (support to institution-building among others), and the incentives of policy actors. Another brief in this series by Anders Olofsgård spells out these points very clearly and references to further readings for those interested.
One aspect I find to be missing in the debate is a reflection on what impact this new method has on the three main actors involved, namely the researchers and practitioners in development and their way of working, and the people living in the countries and regions where these studies take place. This will therefore be the focus of this brief.
The Impact on the Scholarly Profession
The creation of experimental infrastructures and the popularity of the RCT methodology have rubbed off on the rest of the empirical practice in development economics and beyond, with ever-increasing demands and expectations on the econometric identification of new studies. However, when it comes to what is possibly the main weakness of RCTs as compared to most observational studies, namely external validity, the corresponding demands and expectations on how this is dealt with seem to fall behind. As pointed out in Rodrik (2008), it is enough to compare the number of pages spent on describing the identification in an average observational study to that on external validity in an average RCT-based paper. If the purpose is to learn “what works in development”, as opposed to “what worked once for a set of 25 primary schools in Uttar Pradesh faced with high drop out rates” [1], it is natural to expect the researcher that really wants to serve this purpose to provide for a desired generality of her findings. With no generality, the findings may be of limited practical use to politicians and practitioners who need to choose a policy tool or make a decision in conditions, which are likely to differ from the exact setting of the study.
During a recent presentation by one of the most active and prominent RCT researchers, the researcher clearly stated at some point that: “[t]his intervention was never thought for scaling up as a policy.” That made me pause. But what is the purpose, then? In my meaning, these studies should fit into a “bigger-picture” understanding, or at least hypothesizing on how development works, what the binding constraints and open challenges are, what might contribute to overcoming them, and how do we proceed from there. Once some candidates are identified, RCTs might, depending on the setting, be used to evaluate and compare before and after the preferred policy is implemented. Unfortunately, this attitude is far from common, beyond what has become the standard of the ‘Introduction paragraphs’.
Quite often RCT studies are extremely precise and accurate on “the impact of X on Y”, even in cases of very small effects, and can be perhaps a bit vague or face bigger uncertainties on the ‘bigger’ question. This means that many, more general (and very relevant) questions are not addressed by development economists just because a RCT is not feasible. An example mentioned in a recent keynote lecture by David Laitin is the BetterBirth Project. This is a WHO program that seems to be making a big difference for infant and maternal health in India’s poorest states through a list of 29 easy, low-cost, low-technology and well-known practices. The main lesson drawn by observers at the Harvard School of Public Health is that people follow the list more accordingly when it is spread through ”human contact”. No mass media advertisement campaign, no punishment or incentive schemes, just ”nice” people visiting, explaining, and demonstrating the list, while – in the words of an interviewed nurse – ”smiling a lot”. At first sight, this seems like something that could be randomized. However, the treatment is so diffuse and fuzzy that the practical implementation would be very challenging. If it is the case that the person meeting the clinics’ personnel and spreading the information has to be somewhat of a mentor in order for the transition to happen, to be kind and pedagogic, repeat the visits indefinitely to make sure that the practices have been adopted, and do whatever else it takes to make them learn, this is very hard to observe with precision. To simply define X as ”presentation of the list in person”, to be compared to, for example, the ”diffusion of the list through an information campaign” would probably run the risk of severely underestimating the impact. This would be because it would bundle together different types of informers and different levels of human interaction. This means that there would be a high risk of zero or insignificant results from such a study. A RCT would need to be complemented by other investigations, for example surveys, in order to find out if there really was an effect and how it came about. All of the above is likely to undermine the publication chances for an academic paper on the issue, thereby discouraging development scholars to study this program.
There are two main ways of augmenting the RCT methodology in the direction of generalizability and external validity: the elbow-grease approach of replication and the resuscitation of the concern for theoretical mechanisms. Replication studies are not very appealing in the perspective of a scholar that aspires academic publications. Besides completely new clever designs that establish a link of causation in a specific case – and possibly for each of these corresponding studies that establishes the absence of such a link in different settings – journals have little interest in publishing more variations on the same theme. Replications with small variations should instead be highly attractive for development institutions and practitioners, precisely for the reason, mentioned above, that they want to learn about effectiveness of alternative strategies in as many different specific contexts as possible. [2] In an ideal world, development institutions and aid bureaucracies would work in close cooperation with universities and academic institutions, involving young researchers before their career-concern-stress phase (perhaps Ph. D. students?) in the design and evaluation of as many of their planned interventions as possible. Moreover, in an ideal world this would be enough reward for the young researchers. This wealth of replications would then favor the possibility of “taking stock” and really learning about some general truth. I do not, however, have a good recipe for making this happen.
Luckily, some scholars are in the meanwhile working on making the pendulum swing back from the purest empiricism to the involvement with theory. Here is a list of possibilities that are important to reflect about, starting from a given RCT:
– The macro problem. How does the found effect compare to the “bigger issue”, the one that most likely set the scene in the ‘Introduction paragraph’ of the study? Few studies go back to this point, after presenting their results. Numerical simulations or structural estimation of theoretical models might help answering this question. (See some examples in Buera et al. (2011) and Kaboski et al. (2011)).
– The alternative hypothesis. What is the particular intervention compared against? If the set of circumstances or policy-relevant parameters that might be varied are too big or too dense for replications, maybe a theoretical model can help to vary them in a smooth and continuous way?
– The strategic reaction. How are the involved economic agents likely to respond in case of an expansion in space, time or both, of the intervention? How would they have responded in the absence of the intervention?
The Impact on Development Practices
As stated above, RCTs may be a powerful tool for the learning and decision-making in development institutions, public or private. However, this assumes a seldom-questioned willingness to learn and change practices on their part. Brigham et al. (2013) show, through a RCT, that these organizations might be subject to confirmation bias. Brigham et al. sent out an invitation to microfinance institutions, offering partnership to evaluate their programs, randomly accompanying it with a survey of previous studies finding positive impact of microcredit, or a survey of studies finding no impact. The second treatment elicited barely half as many responses as the first one, which suggests that at least this type of organizations might not be so interested in learning whether what they do is effective or can be improved. Coupled with the mentioned publication bias, this might skew the distribution of reported, published and established findings even further.
The Impact on the Local Context
Individual studies can of course be affected by the so-called Hawthorne effect or experimenter effect. The phenomenon, by which the act of being experimented upon changes a subject’s behavior, was first observed and got its name in the 1920s in industrial psychology. Although it is clearly hard to establish, it has for decades been a central criticism of the ”participant observation” methodology in anthropology and ethnography. Also behavioral economists, that more recently started using experiments both in labs and in the field, are explicitly careful about it.
Depending on the definition of causality that the researcher has in mind, the fact that having knowledge about being treated impacts outcomes, might not be an issue at all for the measurement of the overall effect of an intervention. The overall effect should include also the (optimal) reaction of the agents (for example a change in behavior, the adoption of other complementary inputs, etc.) and this is actually considered one of the advantages of the method. However, this raises problems for the interpretation of the size of the effect and the analysis of the channels that bring it about. This point is made very clearly by Bulte et al. (2012), who compare a double-blind RCT with a regular one. If all or most of the effect simply comes from the participants knowing to be ”treated” and reacting to it, is the effect still going to be there when the intervention becomes a regular policy? The majority of both authors and critics mostly ignore this important question.
Beyond the perspective of a single study, a different concern comes to mind when considering how a substantial number of RCT studies are clustered geographically. The map below shows a snapshot of the J-PAL interventions in Africa and Asia, which are only a fraction, albeit substantial, of the total.
Figure 1. J-PAL Interventions in Africa and AsiaReading study after study set in Kenya, or some Indian state, I wonder if people there are starting to get used to private organizations going around giving away assets, or used to temporary local government programs with funky benefit schemes. To my knowledge, no study has yet reflected upon the aggregate impact of experiments and randomized interventions in an area that has many. Might it be the case that exposure to many conditions eventually results in ”experimental fatigue”, or practice effects, which may influence the results of the studies and make the interpretation of the findings difficult?
Even more worrisome, given the frequency of and the resources involved in these interventions, perhaps we should expect an impact on the local political economy. As a parallel, I think about the agrarian reform and the later establishment of the welfare state in post-war Italy, and how they gave major local actors the ability to uphold their clientelistic systems. The newly established rights and entitlements, the various benefits and redistribution programs, were ”filtered” by the local elites and channeled through the traditional ties of family, kinship, friendship and neighborhood. According to comparative analyses of European welfare regimes, clientelism exists, in different forms and intensities, in all Mediterranean welfare states, and it appears to be linked to the process of political mobilization and the establishment of welfare state institutions in these nations.
A recent study by Ravallion et al. (2013) finds that unemployed fail to act on information about the National Employment Guarantee Scheme (NEGS) in India. They hypothesizes that the bottleneck lies with the local government institutions (Gram Panchayats). The GP are supposed to receive the applications and apply for central government resources for planning and implementation of projects, so as to guarantee 100 days of work per year to all adults from rural households who are willing to do unskilled manual labor at the statutory minimum wage. But perhaps – argue the authors – given the strict controls on corruption, the GP officials do not find anything in it for themselves, and hence do not proceed. Of course this is just one of the possible explanations, and moreover the NEGS is not a RCT. But in general the involvement of local official or unofficial power structures in contexts where this type of interventions are increasingly common could be interestingly related to the hypothesis on the ”Mediterranean welfare state” outlined above. The idea definitely deserves investigation.
Conclusions
The popularity of RCTs among development scholars is finally spreading to practitioners. This is mostly good news, there is much to gain and learn from this approach, especially in contexts where it is grossly underexploited, as has been the case in Sweden. However, a near-monopoly of this approach is though not granted, given its non-negligible limitations, often belittled in light of its numerous strengths. Spurring development “one experiment at a time” might take unnecessary extra time and efforts, and bring about other undesirable consequences. Both development scholars and practitioners should not forget the other arrows in their quiver.
References
- Bannerjee, A. and E. Duflo (2008), “The Experimental Approach to Development Economics”, NBER Working Paper 14467.
- Brigham, Matthew, Michael Findley, William Matthias, Chase Petrey, and Daniel Nelson. ”Aversion to Learning in Development? A Global Field Experiment on Microfinance Institutions”. Technical Report, Brigham Young University March 2013.
- Buera, F. J., J. P. Kaboski, and Y. Shin (2011). ”The macroeconomics of microfinance.”
- BREAD working paper.
- Bulte, E., Pan, L., Hella, J., Beekman, G. and S. di Falco (2012). ”Pseudo-Placebo Effects in Randomized Controlled Trials for Development: Evidence from a Double-Blind Field Experiment in Tanzania.” Working Paper.
- Kaboski, J. P. and R. M. Townsend (2011, July). ”A structural evaluation of a large-scale quasi-experimental microfinance initiative.” Econometrica 79, 1357–1406.
- Olofsgård, A. ”What Do Recent Insights From Development Economics Tell Us About Foreign Aid Policy?” FREE Policy Brief Series, October 3, 2011.
- Ravallion, M., et al. ”Try Telling People their Rights? On Making India’s Largest Antipoverty Program work in India’s Poorest State.” Department of Economics, Georgetown University, Washington DC (2013).
- Rodrik, D. (2008). ‘The New Development Economics: We Shall Experiment, but How Shall We Learn?’. Harvard Kennedy School Working Paper No. RWP08-055.▪
[1] The example is fictitious. Any resemblance to real studies is unintended and purely coincidental.
[2] At least in theory – this point is discussed more in the next section.
The Customs Union Between Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan: Some Evidence from the New Tariff Rates and Trade Flows
Author: Arevik Mkrtchyan, European University Institute.
This brief addresses the Customs Union between Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan that was established in 2010. It argues that the external tariff schedule reflects a compromise between the interests of its members rather than simple expansion of Russian influence on the CU partners, and that the reduction in trade costs due to elimination of internal borders, benefits both the members of the CU and their external trade partners. Moreover, the impact of alleviated non-tariff trade costs on trade flows is strong and significant, while the tariff impact is insignificant for all members.
Old-Age Poverty and Health – How Much Does Income Matter?
The question concerning the material situation of older people and its consequences for their wellbeing seems to be more important than ever. This is especially true given rapid demographic changes in the Western World and economic pressures on governments to reduce public spending. We use data from the Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe (SHARE) to examine different aspects of old-age poverty and its possible effects on deterioration in health. The data contains information on representative samples from 12 European countries including the Czech Republic and Poland. We use the longitudinal dimension of the data to go beyond cross sectional associations and analyze transitions in health status controlling for health in the initial period and material conditions. We find that poverty matters for health outcomes in later life. Wealth-defined and subjective poverty correlates much more strongly with health outcomes than income-defined measure. Importantly subjective poverty significantly increases mortality by 58.3% for those aged 50–64 (for details see Adena and Myck, 2013a and 2013b).
Measuring Poverty
When measuring poverty, the standard approach is to define the poverty threshold at 60% of median equalized income. This standardized measure offers some advantages, such as simplicity and comparability with already existing studies. However, there are valid arguments against its use when analyzing old-age poverty. The permanent-income theory provides arguments against current income as a major determinant of quality of life of older people. Moreover, poverty defined with respect to current income while taking account of household size through equalization, ignores other important aspects of living costs such as disability or health expenditures. Additionally, most analysis using income-poverty measures ignore such aspects as housing ownership and housing costs.
Our analysis examines different aspects of poor material conditions of the elderly. The first poverty definition refers to respondents’ wealth as an alternative to income-defined poverty. Poor households, defined with reference to wealth (“wealth poverty” – WEALTH), are those that belong to the bottom third of the wealth distribution of the sample in each country. For this purpose, household wealth is the sum of household real assets (net of any debts) and household gross financial assets. Secondly, we compare the above poverty measures to a subjective measure of material well-being. This measure is based on subjective declarations by respondents, in which case (“subjective poverty” – SUB) individuals are identified as poor on the basis of a question of how easily they can make ends meet. If the answer is “with some” or “with great” difficulty, individuals in the household are classified as “poor”.
One reflection of potential problems with the standard income poverty measure becomes visible when it is compared with the subjective measure. The graph below shows the differences in country rankings when using one or the other poverty measure. The country with the greatest disproportion is Czech Republic. While being ranked as second according to the income measure, it is ninth according to the subjective measure.
Figure 1. Country Ranks in Old-Age Poverty According to an Income versus a Subjective Measure Source: Authors’ calculations using SHARE data (Wave 2, release 2.5.0).Even more striking is the fact that the differences between ranks are not because of over or under classification of individuals as poor, but rather because of misclassification. Figure 2 shows that there is little overlap between different poverty measures. The share of individuals classified as poor according to all three measures is only 7.95%, whereas it is 60% according to at least one of the measures.
Figure 2. Poverty Measure Overlap Notes: Data weighted using Wave 2 sample weights. Source: Authors’ calculations using SHARE data (Wave 2, release 2.5.0).Measuring Well-Being
We examine three binary outcomes measuring the well-being of the respondents – two reflecting physical health, and one measuring individuals’ subjective health. The two measures of physical health are generated with reference to the list of twelve symptoms of bad health and the list of twenty-three limitations in activities of daily living (ADLs). In both cases, we define someone to be in a bad state if they have three or more symptoms or limitations. The two definitions are labelled as: “3+SMT” (three or more symptoms) and “3+ADL” (three or more limitations in ADLs). Subjective health “SUBJ” is defined to be bad if the subjective health assessment is “fair” or “poor”. Finally, we also analyze mortality as an “objective” health outcome.
Poverty and Transitions in Well-Being and Health
There is some established evidence in the literature that poverty negatively affects health and other outcomes at different stages of life.[1] At the same time, there is little evidence on how the choice of the poverty measure might result in under- or over-estimation of the effects of poverty. We address this question by examining different poverty measures as potential determinants of transitions from good to bad states of health.
The results confirm that living in poverty increases an individual’s probability of deterioration of health. In a compact form, Figure 3 presents our results from 12 separate regressions (4 outcomes, three poverty measures). Here we report the odds ratios related to the respective estimated poverty dummies. Individuals classified as poor according to the income measure are 37.7% more likely to report bad subjective health in a later wave of the survey than their richer counterparts; they are 4.5% more likely to suffer from 3 or more symptoms; 18.7% more likely to suffer from 3 or more limitations; and 5% more likely to die. The last three effects, however, are not statistically significant.
In contrast, the effects of wealth-defined poverty and subjectively assessed poverty are 2-8 times stronger than those of income poverty, and they are also significant for all outcomes but death. Overall, wealth-defined poverty and subjective assessment of material well-being strongly correlate with deterioration in physical health (exactly the same goes for improvements in health, see Adena and Myck 2013b).
Figure 3. Poverty and Transitions from Good to Bad States Overlap Notes: Data weighted using Wave 2 sample weights. Source: Authors’ calculations using SHARE data (Wave 2, release 2.5.0, Wave 3, release 1, Wave 4, release 1).Poverty and Mortality in the Age Group 50-64
Our analysis reveals differences between age groups and confirms the decreasing importance of income (and thus income defined poverty) with age. As compared to the average effects presented in Figure 3, for the younger age group 50–64 income poverty proves more important as a determinant of bad outcomes, with transition probabilities between 20 and 40% for all outcomes (see Figure 4). The magnitudes are closer to those of other poverty measures, but still lower in all cases. Importantly, we find that wealth-defined and subjective poverty is an important determinant of death in the age group 50–64.
Figure 4. Poverty and Transitions from Good to Bad States 50-64 Notes: Data weighted using Wave 2 sample weights. Source: Authors’ calculations using SHARE data (Wave 2, release 2.5.0, Wave 3, release 1, Wave 4, release 1).Conclusions
The role of financial conditions for the development of health of older people significantly depends on the measure of material well-being used. In this policy brief, we defined poverty with respect to income, subjective assessment, and relative wealth. Of these three, wealth-defined poverty and subjective assessment of material well-being strongly and consistently correlate with deterioration and improvements in physical and subjective health. We found little evidence that relative income poverty plays a role in changes in physical health of older people. This suggests that the traditional income measure of household material situation may not be appropriate as a proxy for the welfare of older populations, and may perform badly as a measure of improvements in their quality of life or as a target for old-age policies. To be valid, such measures should cover broader aspects of financial well-being than income poverty. They could incorporate aspects of wealth and the subjective assessment of material situations as well as indicators more specifically focused on the consumption baskets of the older population.
▪
References
- Adena, Maja and Michal Myck (2013a): “Poverty and transitions in key areas of quality of life”, in: Börsch-Supan, Axel, Brandt, Martina , Litwin, Howard and Guglielmo Weber (eds.) “Active Ageing and Solidarity between Generations in Europe – First Results from SHARE after the Economic Crisis.”
- Adena, Maja and Michal Myck (2013b) Poverty and Transitions in Health, IZA Discussion Paper 7532, IZA-Bonn.
Development Policy After the Millennium Development Goals: Where Do We Go From Here?
This policy brief reports on a discussion of the Post-2015 Development Agenda held during a full day conference at the Stockholm School of Economics on August 23, 2013. The event was organized jointly by the Stockholm Institute of Transition Economics (SITE) and the Swedish Ministry for Foreign Affairs and was the third installment of Development Day, a yearly development policy conference. The Millennium Development Goals established in year 2000 has been an essential concept for global and national efforts to promote economic, social and human development. Highlighting income poverty, health, education, gender equality and environmental sustainability, the targets have focused global efforts on a set of quantifiable and comparable measures of progress. The question for the development community as these goals reach their endpoint is how to build a successful agenda for the future beyond year 2015. To discuss this challenging question, the conference brought together a distinguished and experienced group of policy oriented scholars and practitioners from governments, International Financial Institutions, the business community as well as NGOs.
In September 2000, world leaders adopted the United Nations Millennium Declaration, committing their nations to a global partnership to reduce extreme poverty. The declaration defined eight time-bound targets expiring in 2015, the so-called Millennium Development Goals (MDGs). These goals specify areas of focus; eradicate extreme poverty and hunger, achieve universal primary education, promote gender equality and empower women, reduce child mortality rates, improve maternal health, combat HIV/AIDS, malaria and other diseases, ensure environmental sustainability, and develop a global partnership for development. They also set explicit targets such as halving the number of people living on less than US$ 1.25 a day and reducing maternal mortality by three quarters from 1990 to 2015. Some commendable success has indeed been realized; already in 2010 the worldwide goal to reduce by half the proportion of people living on less than US$ 1.25 a day was achieved. However, much less progress has been seen in some other areas, including maternal health, and there are countries for which none of the goals are expected to be achieved by 2015. Nevertheless, the use of quantifiable, comparable and time-bound targets to create awareness and direct political resources is generally regarded as a success. The question for the development community as 2015 quickly approaches is thus how to build a successful post-2015 development agenda that builds on what has worked but also incorporates areas identified as missing.
The process to establish a new agenda of course raises many questions and reveals some of the trade-offs involved. There seems to be a consensus that the Millennium Declaration and the MDG framework should serve as a starting point, but there are many details to pin down. For instance, there are important challenges not directly mentioned in the original eight goals such as political conflict, rising inequality and youth unemployment. Many also argue that environmental sustainability, though included, may deserve a more prominent role in the future agenda. On the other hand, loading the Agenda with more and more goals may also dilute the global effort across too many areas, and some scholars argue that the whole idea with specific goals is counterproductive based on an organic view of development ill-suited for social engineering from above. To protect credibility, it is also important to get a sense of what is realistic to aim for, and what responsibility to ascribe to the already developed world. Moreover, even if a consensus can be reached with regards to the goals, opinions on how to best reach those goals will most definitely vary widely.
To get the process towards a new agenda started, the UN Secretary General has launched several initiatives including task teams, special advisors and consultations, but also a High-level Panel of Eminent Persons co-chaired by the Presidents of Indonesia and Liberia, and the Prime Minister of the United Kingdom; also including as its member Gunilla Carlsson, Swedish Minister for Development Cooperation. The panel, led by executive secretary and lead author Homi Kharas, submitted a report to the Secretary General on May 31. The program of Development Day 2013 started with a presentation of the report by Dr. Kharas, and remarks from Minister Carlsson. This was followed by an academic session corroborating projections of the report and outlining its limitations, and two panel discussions on sustainable development and Sweden’s potential as a leader in this process. Below follows a short representation of the main arguments and debates of the day.
A New Global Partnership: Eradicate Poverty and Transform Economies through Sustainable Development
Homi Kharas, Senior Fellow and Deputy Director at the Brookings Institution, presented the main messages contained in the report in the first session. An analysis of the situation since year 2000 shows many positive signs such as high global economic growth; increased international connectedness; a reduction in global inequality; and a substantial drop in absolute poverty rates. However, there are also many challenges ahead; rapid population growth, political conflicts, and the fact that the majority of the extremely poor live in conflict zones, increasing urbanization, a deteriorating environment and dwindling aid flows. This, in turn, leads Dr. Kharas to conclude that ‘business as usual’ is no longer feasible, and a new framework replacing the MDGs is needed.
The report seeks to address these issues and is conceived to serve as a set of guidelines, new goals and targets for the UN Secretary General and for the UN member states for the post-2015 period. At the core of the report is a bold aspiration to eradicate absolute poverty by 2030 through a unified framework of sustainable economic growth, increased social equality and environmental sustainability, and a new global partnership paradigm. This universal agenda, in turn, is proposed to be reached via five paradigm shifts to the status quo, (i) universal inclusion and equality, (ii) environmentally sustainable development, (iii) a transformation of national economies for sustainable growth, (iv) peace and effective, transparent public institutions, and (v) a new and more inclusive global partnership. In the report these broad and major shifts are further delineated across 12 illustrative targets, which, if met, will directly affect more than two billion people across the world and would require about $30 trillion spent by the governments worldwide.
Dr, Kharas emphasized that the report was prepared in cooperation with 5000 civil organizations, 250 large international corporations, and thematic, regional and country consultations all over the world, with another one million people taking part in an online questionnaire. He stressed that this kind of broad cooperation and consultation is needed to implement the goals set by the report and especially to operationalize these goals at the level of each of the member states.
Gunilla Carlsson, Swedish Minister for International Development Cooperation and a member of the UN High-Level Panel, continued the discussion and commended the members of the Panel on the impressive amount of work put in the report. She also emphasized the universal character of the agenda presented in the report, largely applicable both to developing and developed countries.
Carlsson stressed what she identified as the core values of the report; eradication of extreme poverty, prevention of violence and conflict, and inclusive peace. She further underlined the importance of local and global partnerships across governments, business communities and civil society. Broader public-private partnerships are essential both for fostering innovation in development work and to guarantee sufficient amounts of financing. The exact design of such a framework, however, is still an open question, but she hopes Sweden can serve as a leading example.
Both Homi Kharas and Gunilla Carlsson also showed great optimism when asked about the potential to implement the substantive initiatives by 2030. They stressed that not only does the world at present have more resources and more aid flows than it ever have, but the international community, including both public and private actors, is also showing more willingness to help the developing countries integrate successful development models than ever before.
Comments and Reflections
Martin Ravallion, Edmond D. Villani Professor of Economics at Georgetown University, started the commentary and reflection session. He showed how there is a strong current trend of between-country convergence of inequality rates (more equal countries becoming more unequal, while more unequal countries are becoming more equal) and declining poverty rate. The latter decline is to a considerable extent driven by Chinese economic growth, but this is far from the only source. He also underlined that the rate of poverty reduction has increased since the adoption of the MDGs in the 2000s, but said it was too early to judge the success or failure of the MDGs on these grounds.
Based on current trends, Ravallion also presented some estimates of the possibility to achieve the core objective of the report, eradication of absolute poverty by 2030. From a broad range of alternatives, the best case scenario, based on 3% annual growth rates of the world economy, absence of major economic crises and at least not decreasing participation of the poor in the benefits of growth, estimated a fall in absolute poverty rates from about 19% at present to 3% by 2030. In a less optimistic scenario, but historically not unlikely, levels of inequality and poverty would fall at a much slower rate, causing 12% to 14% of the world population to live below the absolute poverty line by 2030. Thus, the conclusion is that total eradication of absolute poverty by 2030 is hardly achievable, but substantial progress can be made, and it depends critically on continued high levels of world economic growth.
Professor Ravallion also stressed that these projections were made possible through a recent revolution in data availability, something the High Level Panel was asking for. To a large extent, this is attributed to a massive data collection effort by the World Bank, which not only provided better coverage of countries around the world, but also allowed for deeper insights into the nature of extreme poverty, including re-calculations and harmonization of cross-country comparable Purchasing Power Parity consumption baskets. This revolution provided more reliable inputs for his prediction models and improved the precision of estimates considerably.
Owen Barder, Senior Fellow and Director for Europe at the Center for Global Development, further emphasized this importance of credible statistics. Barder was somewhat skeptical to the report’s claim to be bold and offering a new approach, arguing that it largely reiterated the goals (jobs for young people, partnership with the private sector, reform of the financial system, etc.) already in the Millennium Declaration from year 2000. He also argued that the claim of success for the MDGs is almost entirely made on the basis of paragraph 19 of the Declaration; the objective to reduce by half the number of people living in absolute poverty. Much less progress has been made on the other explicit objectives, and all other aspects emphasized in the Millennium Declaration but which were not necessarily a part of the MDGs.
Barder suggested that there is too little effort to consistently measure whether rich countries are playing their part in the global partnership. Against that background he presented some preliminary results on the last round of the Center for Global Development’s Commitment to Development Index, calculated on the basis of OECD counties’ participation in aid, trade, investments, migration, environment, security and technology transfers. Over the last 10 years, OECD countries demonstrated on average a modest increase from four to five points on a ten-point scale, with Sweden ranked third from the top with a score of 7.2 for 2011 and 6.8 for 2012. Interestingly enough, this deterioration in the index for Sweden is mainly due to deterioration in the security component of the index, in turn resulting from larger sales of arms to undemocratic regimes, and from decreasing aid and immigration. There is obviously variation across countries, but on average there is scant improvements during the 13 years since the Millennium Declaration. This led Barder to question whether the developed countries have contributed their share to the objective of ending poverty, or if too much of the heavy lifting is left for the developing countries.
Barder concluded the presentation by pointing out the difference in language used in the report, namely the imperative used in the parts of the report describing recommendations for the developing countries, and the subjunctive used for recommendations for the developed countries. Again, to him this difference signaled the need to re-emphasize the importance of political commitment and operational goals also for the already developed countries in the Post-2015 Agenda.
Johan Rockström, Executive Director at the Stockholm Resilience Centre, started out noting that the population of the world is estimated to increase to eight billion people by 2030 and to nine billion by 2050. This, in combination with the currently prevailing development paradigm that emphasizes short-term economic growth over long run sustainability, causing degradation of biodiversity and climate change, means that we are hitting the planetary ceiling of eco-capacity. This suggests that ‘business as usual’ is no longer an option, and a new development paradigm is needed.
To address this issue, Rockström formulated a set of goals for human development balancing the needs of the environment, the needs of society and the needs of the people, all within the Earth’s life-support system. He proposed a broader framework for thinking about these issues, the so-called Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs rather than MDGs), which rebalances the relative weight on environmental, human and economic development with relatively more emphasis on the first two. This approach unifies the MDGs with planetary necessities (material use, clean air, nutrient and hydrological cycles, biodiversity, and climate stability), and sustainable development goals (sustainable food and water security, universal clean energy, governance for sustainable societies, etc.).
Discussion Panels
The first panel of the day focused on issues of sustainable development and was started by Klas Waldenström, Senior Advisor on the Post-2015 Development Agenda at Sida. He argued that the main challenge to the new partnership paradigm discussed earlier, will be the creation of trust both across nations and across the private and public sectors. Referring to the experience of Sida, he cited the successful creation of a network of 25 private Swedish companies focusing on models of sustainable development. An important role of official foreign aid in these partnerships, he argued, was to blend direct financial transfers with a combination of political support and business sector outreach, thereby potentially leveraging the financial flows with alternative sources of capital.
David Fergusson, Deputy Director at the Office of Science and Technology at USAID, called for more and better data in order to be able to operationalize and evaluate the new strategies that hopefully will come out of the report. He also reiterated the importance of transformative solutions for sustainable development and the need to understand that ‘business as usual’ is no longer an option. He also referred to the successful cooperation between Sida and USAID as an example of international collaboration of a new kind, more of which will be needed in the future to overcome the status quo and achieve the goals put forward by the report.
Garry Conille, Special Advisor to President Ellen Johnson Sirleaf of Liberia and UNDP, discussed his experience of working with the MDGs and stressed that possibly the most challenging part was the negotiation between different stakeholders to reach a set of issues well-defined and contained enough to be operational. From his point of view, the major challenge is the operationalization of the rather opaque and broadly defined MDGs and how to find a proper allocation of resources across the many commendable ambitions. He therefore called for an effort to make the post-2015 agenda more practical.
The issue of operationalization was discussed further by Stefano Prato, Managing Director at the Society for International Development. He argued that with such large shifts proposed by the post-2015 agenda, it is perhaps difficult to understand how to work with the vision put forward by the panel. His suggestion for the Panel was to dig deeper into the challenging areas of the report but also to develop more applied recommendations for the member states and especially so for the private institutions desired as part of the new partnerships.
This need for operationalization was supported by Jakob Granit, Centre Director at the Stockholm Environment Institute. In his opinion, the broad vision as presented in the report is indeed difficult to work with, but he also suggested that progress on parts of the agenda can be instructive for how to go further also with the more challenging parts. He also emphasized the importance of a regional approach, building on existing networks of regional partnerships, and again stressed the importance of public-private partnerships to solve common international issues.
The second panel was devoted to the role Sweden can play in global sustainable development and the post-2015 agenda. The discussion was started by Ulla Holm, Global Director at Tetra Laval Food for Development Office. She presented some of Tetra Laval’s experiences of sustainable development work in Bangladesh, an example of a successful public-private partnership. In her view, one of the main pillars of sustainability is to prevent unnecessary food loss, and this can be achieved by building an integrated value chain that supports rural development in the long run. The crucial challenge on this path is the need for concurrent public and private investments, and how to overcome coordination problems and lacking trust across stakeholders. She therefore stressed the need to construct successful public-private partnerships on a large scale and in different areas, but also to make sure to document and scale up the existing models in order to replicate success in the most cost efficient way.
Erik Lysen, Director for International Affairs at the Church of Sweden, stressed the challenges in changing existing institutions and briefly discussed the main motives that could make such changes to occur. He also argued that some of the strongest motives that would actually provide the necessary motivation for change, namely fear, could not be desirable in the long run, but still viable in a context of post-2015 agenda if complemented with better social protection, institutes of civil society and a broader public discussion. Here, NGOs could act as watchdogs and catalysts, strengthening the desire for building new institutions and providing material and human support for their construction at the same time.
Stefan Isaksson, Head of Policy Analysis at the Department for Aid Management at the Ministry for Foreign Affairs, continued the discussion on the challenges of changing existing institutions. He described current efforts to remodel the Swedish aid management system in order to become a more effective bureaucracy. In his view, the major shift in thinking is that of understanding aid less as simply giving money away and more as an investment for a common future. This is needed to improve the selection process of aid projects and also to motivate better the need to make projects and their results measurable and accountable. To achieve this, broader collaboration and consultations across stakeholders is needed. He also mentioned that perhaps at present many aid projects are too conservative, that the failure rate is too low because it reflects an aversion to risk that partly defeats the purpose of official foreign aid. The private sector will always be reluctant to venture into areas with high risk even if the potential social rate of return is high, so for official aid to serve as a more effective complement to private flows, more risk tolerance may be needed.
The issue of understanding aid as investment was discussed in detail by Jonas Ahlen, Investment Manager at the Storebrand Kapitalförvaltning. He described current efforts in the area of sustainable investments, mainly centered in microfinance and agricultural loans. In his opinion, broader involvement in such practices from the private sector would facilitate a transition to sustainable practices, but would at the same time require changing existing regulations in home countries to incentivize and alleviate the risks. He also stressed the need for broader public-private partnerships in these areas and briefly described the new consultative practices established by the Ministry of Finance in Sweden to catalyze private capital participation in for instance infrastructure projects in Sub-Saharan Africa.
Finally, Homi Kharas added to the Sweden-centered discussion by stressing that there exists no systematic assessment of what public-private partnerships can do. In his opinion, possibly the most important role for Sweden is to create conditions that would facilitate public-private partnerships in development and aid. By developing and experimenting with forms of public-private partnerships, as well as with new ways of measuring and monitoring of performance of such partnerships, Sweden could create a case for broader involvement of private funding and thus accomplish perhaps the most difficult part of bridging the post-2015 with the experience and skills of the private sector.
Conclusions
In sum, the discussion at the Development Day 2013 clearly highlighted the importance of sustaining some of the positive trends seen lately for economic and human development but also highlighted how crucial it is to take environmental sustainability into account. There is a growing consensus that long run human development necessitates an understanding of the planetary boundaries, even though exactly what trade-offs this involves and where to put the relative weight on more short run economic development is still debatable. There was also a wide consensus around the importance to get all different parts of society involved and working in tandem. Foreign aid cannot be expected to pull the heavy load by itself. The challenges are far too wide and important. Instead, much hope was attributed to public-private partnerships, but there is a lot of work that remains to make sure these vehicles generate the hoped for solutions. The capital, experience and skills of the private sector are needed. On the other hand, getting the incentives right is not a trivial challenge. Finding models of partnerships that work and can be scaled up may be an area in which Sweden can set an example and lead the way for other nations striving to contribute to long run sustainable development.